To install click the Add extension button. That's it.

The source code for the WIKI 2 extension is being checked by specialists of the Mozilla Foundation, Google, and Apple. You could also do it yourself at any point in time.

4,5
Kelly Slayton
Congratulations on this excellent venture… what a great idea!
Alexander Grigorievskiy
I use WIKI 2 every day and almost forgot how the original Wikipedia looks like.
What we do. Every page goes through several hundred of perfecting techniques; in live mode. Quite the same Wikipedia. Just better.
.
Leo
Newton
Brights
Milds

Trygve Haavelmo

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Trygve Magnus Haavelmo
Born(1911-12-13)13 December 1911
Died26 July 1999(1999-07-26) (aged 87)
NationalityNorwegian
Academic career
InstitutionUniversity of Aarhus
University of Chicago
University of Oslo
University College London
FieldMacroeconomics, econometrics
School or
tradition
Neo-Keynesian economics
Alma materUniversity of Oslo
InfluencesJohn Maynard Keynes
Ragnar Frisch
Jan Tinbergen
ContributionsProbability approach in econometrics
Balanced budget multiplier
AwardsNobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1989)
Information at IDEAS / RePEc

Trygve Magnus Haavelmo (13 December 1911 – 28 July 1999), born in Skedsmo, Norway, was an economist whose research interests centered on econometrics. He received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1989.

YouTube Encyclopedic

  • 1/5
    Views:
    969
    13 629
    350
    2 578
    738
  • Trygve Haavelmo
  • The Work Behind The Nobel Prize: UChicago Experts on Eugene F. Fama and Lars Peter Hansen
  • noble memorial Prize Laureates in Economics 1969-2020 #nobleprize #noblePrizeInEconomics
  • Robust Two-Step Confidence Sets, and the trouble with the First Stage F-statistic
  • Econometrics and time series analysis :-Hiranya K Nath

Transcription

Biography

After attending Oslo Cathedral School,[1] Haavelmo received a degree in economics from the University of Oslo in 1930 and eventually joined the Institute of Economics with the recommendation of Ragnar Frisch. Haavelmo was Frisch's assistant for a period of time until he was appointed as head of computations for the institute. In 1936, Haavelmo studied statistics at University College London while he subsequently traveled to Berlin, Geneva, and Oxford for additional studies.[2] Haavelmo assumed a lecturing position at the University of Aarhus in 1938 for one year and then in the subsequent year was offered an academic scholarship to travel abroad and study in the United States. During World War II he worked with Nortraship in the Statistical Department in New York City. He received his PhD in 1946 for his work on The Probability Approach in Econometrics.[citation needed]

He was a professor of economics and statistics at the University of Oslo between 1948–79 and was the trade department head of division from 1947–48. Haavelmo acquired a prominent position in modern economics through his logical critique of a series of custom conceptions in mathematical analysis.[citation needed]

In 1989, Haavelmo was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics "for his clarification of the probability theory foundations of econometrics and his analyses of simultaneous economic structures."[3]

Haavelmo resided at Østerås in Bærum.[4] He died on 28 July 1999 in Oslo.[citation needed]

Legacy

Judea Pearl wrote "Haavelmo was the first to recognize the capacity of economic models to guide policies" and "presented a mathematical procedure that takes an arbitrary model and produces quantitative answers to policy questions". According to Pearl, "Haavelmo's paper, 'The Statistical Implications of a System of Simultaneous Equations',[5] marks a pivotal turning point, not in the statistical implications of econometric models, as historians typically presume, but in their causal counterparts."[6] Haavelmo's idea that an economic model depicts a series of hypothetical experiments and that policies can be simulated by modifying equations in the model became the basis of all currently used formalisms of econometric causal inference.[citation needed] (The biostatistics and epidemiology literature on causal inference draws from different sources.[7]) It was first operationalized by Robert H. Strotz and Herman Wold (1960)[8] who advocated "wiping out" selected equations, and then translated into graphical models as "wiping out" incoming arrows.[9][10] This operation has subsequently led to Pearl's "do"-calculus[11][12] and to a mathematical theory of counterfactuals in econometric models.[13][14] Pearl further speculates that the reason economists do not generally appreciate these revolutionary contributions of Haavelmo is because economists themselves have still not reached consensus of what an economic model stands for, as attested by profound disagreements among econometric textbooks.[15]

References

  1. ^ "Oslo Katedralskole - en skole med tradisjoner". Om skolen (in Norwegian). Oslo katedralskole. Archived from the original on 19 April 2014. Retrieved 19 April 2014.
  2. ^ "Trygve Haavelmo". University of Oslo. Retrieved 4 January 2016.
  3. ^ Prokesch, Steven (12 October 1989). "Norwegian Wins Nobel For His Work in Economics". The New York Times.
  4. ^ "Sky Nobelpros-vinner stakk fra pressen" (in Norwegian). Norwegian News Agency. 11 October 1989.
  5. ^ Haavelmo, T. (1943). "The statistical implications of a system of simultaneous equations". Econometrica. Reprinted in D.F. Hendry and M.S. Morgan (Eds.), The Foundations of Econometric Analysis, Cambridge University Press, New York, 440–453, 1995. 11 (1): 1–43. doi:10.2307/1905714. JSTOR 1905714.
  6. ^ Pearl, Judea (2015). "Trygve Haavelmo and the Emergence of Causal Calculus". Econometric Theory. 31: 152–179. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.687.1860. doi:10.1017/S0266466614000231. S2CID 232151859.
  7. ^ Rubin, Donald (2005). "Causal inference using potential outcomes: Design, modeling, decisions". Journal of the American Statistical Association. 100 (469): 322–331. doi:10.1198/016214504000001880. S2CID 842793.
  8. ^ Strotz, R.H.; Wold, H.O.A. (1960). "Recursive versus nonrecursive systems: An attempt at synthesis". Econometrica. 28 (2): 417–427. doi:10.2307/1907731. JSTOR 1907731. S2CID 6584147.
  9. ^ Pearl, Judea (1993). "Comment: Graphical models, causality, and intervention". Statistical Science. 8 (3): 266–269. doi:10.1214/ss/1177010894.
  10. ^ Spirtes, P.; Glymour, C. N.; Scheines, R. (1993). Causation, prediction, and search. New York, NY: Springer-Verlag.
  11. ^ Pearl, Judea (1994). Lopez de Mantaras, R.; Poole, D. (eds.). "A probabilistic calculus of actions". Uncertainty in Artificial Intelligence 10: 454–462. arXiv:1302.6835.
  12. ^ Pearl, Judea (2000). Causality: Models, Reasoning, and Inference (2nd (2009) ed.). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
  13. ^ Balke, Alex; Pearl, Judea (1995). Besnard, P.; Hanks, S. (eds.). "Counterfactuals and policy analysis in structural models". Uncertainty in Artificial Intelligence 11: 11–18.
  14. ^ Pearl, Judea (2009). Causality: Models, Reasoning, and Inference. Chapter 7 (2nd ed.). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
  15. ^ Chen, Bryant; Pearl, Judea (2013). "Regression and Causation: A Critical Examination of Six Econometrics Textbooks" (PDF). Real-World Economics Review. 65: 2–20.

External links

Awards
Preceded by Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics
1989
Succeeded by
This page was last edited on 26 October 2023, at 02:55
Basis of this page is in Wikipedia. Text is available under the CC BY-SA 3.0 Unported License. Non-text media are available under their specified licenses. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc. WIKI 2 is an independent company and has no affiliation with Wikimedia Foundation.