To install click the Add extension button. That's it.

The source code for the WIKI 2 extension is being checked by specialists of the Mozilla Foundation, Google, and Apple. You could also do it yourself at any point in time.

4,5
Kelly Slayton
Congratulations on this excellent venture… what a great idea!
Alexander Grigorievskiy
I use WIKI 2 every day and almost forgot how the original Wikipedia looks like.
Live Statistics
English Articles
Improved in 24 Hours
Added in 24 Hours
What we do. Every page goes through several hundred of perfecting techniques; in live mode. Quite the same Wikipedia. Just better.
.
Leo
Newton
Brights
Milds

John Tilley (civil servant)

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The Sir John Tilley stained glass window in St Saviour, Pimlico

Sir John Tilley KCB (20 January 1813 – 18 March 1898) was Secretary to the General Post Office of the United Kingdom.

YouTube Encyclopedic

  • 1/3
    Views:
    8 897
    1 384
    783
  • 40 Years of Public Management Reform - Professor Christopher Pollitt
  • TEDxVillanovaU - Patrick Maggitti - It's Not Just for Artists Anymore: The Creativity Imperative
  • Anthony Trollope

Transcription

APPLAUSE I hope this is working. Is it working? Good. And thank you very much Matthew for the introduction, I had hoped you might go on for about 40 minutes, but I see now that the moment of truth has arrived and I have to start talking. However, I can avoid that for a moment by doing some housekeeping which I've been instructed to do, you understand, I'm obedient. I need to point out that in the Lancaster Room from 2.50 pm until 4.50 pm there is a Policy and Politics, most cited papers panel which, I am assured, will enable anyone, who wants to publish in any journal to have instant success if they listen to the words of wisdom from the authors of the most cited papers in the history of Policy and Politics nay, the world, the universe. So don't miss that. Did I do that all right? Was that OK? Good. Thank you also to David and Sarah for inviting me. I don't think I have the Bristol credentials that some of your other plenary speakers have had so I'm doubly delighted to be invited as a kind of outsider. I have been to Bristol before, but that's about it. It was a long time ago. However, you probably didn't realise when you invited me, that it would coincide so exactly, with my return to the United Kingdom after 16 years. My stuff was delivered to an apartment in Brighton last Friday. And if I have bits of cardboard still stuck to me, that is the reason why. So this is like a double homecoming - domestic and academic and I'm still a little bit disorientated by it all. As was the case with Rod's presentation this morning, there is a paper, a substantial paper, full of the usual academic paraphernalia and if any of you wish to access that, just send me an email. I don't think it's on a website anywhere yet, but I'd be happy to send you a copy. So now, we get to the beginning. I thought it was an appropriate topic, for this conference, for obvious reasons. I would stress that this is public management form in UK central government, I say very little about local government which, I've had a number of discussions with people who actually know about local government, unlike me and they suggest to me that things are rather different there. And I'm happy to accept their expert judgement. So this is just about central government reforms. There are a number of reasons why I think that this is a reasonably important topic. Not least that we've had so many of these reforms and we continue to have, a very high volume of structural and process type reforms, in central government. Now, if I begin with what is relatively the good news Um, something slightly funny has gone... It's cutting off the top of my slides It's probably not desperately important but if anybody knows how to fix that, The top of the the slide says.. "The UK as a world leader in public management reform" and some evidence for that is, simply the volume of reform that we've had almost unceasing. Every now and then you get two or three years without something being, but.. basically, fairly unceasing, large scale reforms 1970 - 2012. A lot of people talk about the New Zealand catharsis of 1984-1993 as the most pure and radical piece of public management reform in recent history. I would argue that the British record is of even more radical reform because the British intensity of reform may not have been quite equal to that spike in New Zealand, but it's gone on for much, much longer. New Zealand has calmed down after 1993. And they hadn't done much at all before 1984. Whereas in the UK, it has gone on, and on, and on. UK examples, in consequence perhaps, are very frequently cited in the international literature. I'm not talking about the specifically domestic literature here. Both the practitioner literature and the academic literature. The Cabinet Office and DfID and its predecessors have been active internationally for many years in actively promoting, marketing, selling, UK management ideas and practices. And in my wanderings around the world I've several times bumped into Cabinet Office people who are frankly selling, one or other aspect of the British model. And the international organizations which have been centrally engaged in developing, the international practitioner thinking, and rhetoric, on public management reform, have been organizations which have been quite heavily populated by Brits or quite heavily influenced by British ideas. So in all those respects, the UK has been, a leader and a major player globally, in public management reform. I have, in the paper, a citation of Stephen Dorrell who was then a junior treasury minister, making a speech in 1993, during the Major administration, where he said, very directly, "The marketizing reforms of Thatcher and Major.." "..are a model which the whole of the rest of the world is now following.." "..and it's not surprising, because they work.". This is a somewhat megalomaniac vision of the role of the UK, but not entirely without echoes overseas. So that's the good news. We can award ourselves a gold medal for public management reform. Now let's turn to the slightly less good news. If we ask some questions about this reform, I would argue that we find a number of slightly, curious or disturbing features. First of all, there's remarkably little, reliable and warranted knowledge, of the actual outcomes, of any of this reform. That's not to say that there aren't endless stories and anecdotes. Particularly in the practitioner world, but also in the academic world, about what's been successful and what's not. But in terms of the kind of stuff, that orthodox social sciences, if such creatures still exist, would regard as reasonably firm evidence, there is practically none. And I'm not standing out as a radical commentator here. I believe in saying that I'm fairly much mainstream, in the academic world. I think Rod Rhodes and Christopher Hood, who was here this morning, would both probably say, much the same thing. And so would a number of other people. Secondly, which is in a way, more disturbing than the first point, there's very little sign that the governments, who have carried out these reforms, have themselves been, in the least bit interested in discovering the consequences. I could come back to that if you like. But what Christopher Hood and Ruth Dixon, have recently, more or less, completed, a massive statistical exercise, on the Thatcher and Major, efficiency reforms, of the 1980s and early 1990s. And the broad conclusion they've come to, is that there was no measurable efficiency gain. Yes, of course, you know you can look at individual, reign of scrutinies, or whatever, and you can find quite significant gains, and little bits of savings. But when you look at the big picture of departmental running costs, and departmental outputs, insofar as there is any official data by which you can measure those things, they do not show, a significant efficiency, gain. There's a little bit of bumping up and down over time, but overall, no. And again, I think, Christopher would say, that one of the most curious aspects of this is that, it's he, and Ruth Dixon, who've been left researching this in 2010, 2011, 2012. Because the governments themselves, neither ministers, nor senior civil servants, have shown ANY interest in putting this data together before. They've shown no interest in checking whether, the programmes they themselves have instigated, have actually resulted in the things that they said they'd result in. That's not to say that nothing has been learned, I do want to emphasise, that I think in terms of, the process of reform, obviously, so many senior officials have been involved in it, that many of them will have picked up all sorts of useful practitioner wisdom about how you do this stuff. but that's very different from, having knowledge of what the, final outcomes and effects are. Whether efficiency, in terms of a ratio between inputs and outputs, or the effectiveness, of public services, or the, the ultimate perceived quality as far as the citizens using those services.. Have any of those things changed, as a result of the reforms? That's a different kind of knowledge. And that seems to be much more thin on the ground. What I'd like to do very, very quickly just to, fill in the picture a little bit, and give you a little bit more evidence, is to look at, a sample or a selection, of some of the big reform white papers, over the 40 year period. And to ask about, their content. The continuities and the discontinuities in them. And these are the ones that I've chosen. The Heath government 1970 reorganization, the Thatcher 1981, efficiency in government. John Major's citizen's charter. Blair's modernising government, which would have been a little bit earlier if he hadn't had problems with the relevant minister, and the more recent coalition open public services white paper, which I'm sure you'll all be much more familiar with than I. All these are, They're chosen deliberately because they are broad scope, public management reform programmes. They're not confined to one sector. Obviously there have been lots more reform white papers than that. Thatcher's 1989, working for patients reform of the National Health Service, was a huge reform, but it was a sectoral reform. These are horizontal reforms. They all come reasonably early in the life of the government. So you could say, that this is before these governments have been blown to badly off-course. Perhaps you could argue, that they embody, some of the fresh ideas that these governments have brought into government and hope to implement. Now changes and continuities. Looking across these five, white papers. First of all, a very obvious, perhaps slightly superficial change, is that the white papers have got much longer, and they're no longer white. They've become much glossier. They are written in a different way now, they're written in a kind of populist, jargon. The first two, the dividing line there, comes between the 1970 and 1981, on the one hand, and John Major's citizen's charter. Somewhere in the 1980s, the nature of these white papers changed. Before that, they were essentially the government deigning to tell the rest of us how they were going to put their own house in order. It was like, "We're going to do this..", "we" being the authority on the machinery of government, indeed it was then called the machinery of government, "and we're going to adjust the machinery in this way", "in order to achieve these improvements". And the first two are focussed very much on ministries. So the reorganization of central government, was about central government. It was about central policy making machinery, and big ministries. The 1981 thing was about, efficiencies and saving money and cutting out waste, by applying business-like techniques, primarily in ministries. The later ones have broadened their scope. to include the whole of the public sector, and by the 2011 white paper, beyond the public sector. You can think of this as a shift in governance if you want to be fancy about it, but certainly many more actors are being brought in. The 1999 Blair white paper, very much included, local authorities, partners, in the non-profit and for-profit sectors. It covered a much wider range than the earlier papers. So that's something of a change. The field of activity, or the scope of ideas about public management reform, seems to have enlarged very considerably. Another change is that, connected with this co-owner voice thing, is that the citizen was barely, present, in the first two white papers, it was an addressee that played no other part in them. in the first two, government was just saying what it was going to do with its own stuff. By the time you get to the 2011 white paper, the citizen is smattered all over it. Or a notional citizen, perhaps I should say, is smattered all over it. And it's the same citizen who is, much mentioned, in the Blair 1999 white paper "Modernising Government". It is the actively choosing, consumer style citizen. John Clarke and Janet Newman have each written, very persuasively, and given some fine grain to, to this discussion of how this image, of the citizen has been gradually, or sometimes rather rapidly, transformed into the consumer citizen, who still seems to be the most popular, kind of citizen with the coalition government, as he, or she, was with the Blair and Brown administrations. Now for the continuity. Now the continuity is rather striking, when you see it. But it's.. It's not necessarily, obvious. It's kind of one of those things that suddenly strikes you. Now these are documents about management. primarily. Policy making, but mainly about management. They all share, right over the forty year period, three characteristics and all three are the absence of something. First of all, none of them documents the need for reform. They provide virtually no evidence on that. The nearest you come to evidence, is the mention of a stereotype, usually. We must reduce bureaucracy. We must make the administration more responsive to citizens. In the latest one, the accusation that the public sector has, not merely ignored but in some ways, actively amplified inequalities between services to different groups of citizens in different areas etc. etc. No evidence is offered for this, whatsoever, in any of these papers. it maybe true I'm not saying it's untrue, I'm just saying that these white papers are evidently not the vehicle for persuading us, by offering us any evidence. Secondly, none of them has any targets. Now these are management documents. They're white papers, but they're about management. You might say, in the era of performance management, you would expect them to have some targets. They don't. The nearest things to targets occur in the, 1991 citizen's charter. Where there are some things which, If you are reasonably generous in your use of language, you could say that they are quasi targets, that we will have certain things in place, within a number of years. And third, and perhaps most important, or most surprising of all, none of them are costed. There are no costings in, anywhere. Some of these reforms, absolutely gigantic, We know how expensive reorganization can be, in all sorts of ways. The transactional costs, and sometimes the direct costs of reform, are very considerable. If you don't believe me, go and read some of the National Audit Office reports, on some recent central government reorganisations. And that information is just not there. So do they, in the absence of costs or targets, do they have any built-in method of checking or evaluation? Answer.. No. In none of them, except, again, the citizen's charter. Which, of course, many of us, mea culpa, laughed at, at the time. You remember, the Steve Bell cartoons, of John Major wearing Superman underpants and all that. A lot of fun was made of the citizen's charter, but actually it was the only one of these reforms, where there was a staged programme of assessment and reassessment, with a degree of independence in that. And reporting to parliament. So there were one, two, three... I think at least three, evaluations going out. Two years, five years.. of what was happening. So, this is a bit strange, this is a strange kind of reform. If you go into other areas, away from public management, you would expect white papers to have some evidence, to have some costings, and to have some targets, but we don't get that, in public management reform. But what we do get is a lot of promises. They're not short on promises. These are just the kernel of these papers. 1970: more coordinated, strategic approach. 1981: Modern business techniques, will eliminate waste and lower public spending etc. etc. You can see them up there. I've already said, we don't have much evidence about what happened, but can we get any handle at all on, on whether these promises were met? I would say, a little bit, but it's often very difficult. 1970: more coordinated, strategic approach to policy making if you think about the last year of the Heath administration and its fall I think you will be stretching a point to describe that as coordinated and strategic. And indeed, some of the, instruments and processes, which Heath introduced were, were subsequently ditched. The rational policy making models of programme analysis and review, the central policy review stuff. The giant departments didn't last long. Central policy review stuff lasted into the Thatcher era, but it was a very much weakened animal. And so on.. Better evidence based. Who knows? Interesting that evidence based policy making, is not actually the flavour of 2012, but it was the flavour of 1970. Of October 1970 and it comes back every now and then, ever since. 1981: modern business techniques, will eliminate waste and lower public spending. Well there is no doubt, that in some specific instances, they increased efficiency, and lowered costs. However.. the work I've already referred to by Hood and Dixon, and other work by Dunleavy, and earlier work, also by Christopher Hood, with Andrew Dunsire, seems to indicate that, number one, public expenditure as a percentage of GDP, certainly didn't go down during the Thatcher era. It was more or less exactly the same at the end as it was the beginning. And secondly, it now seems that, while there may have been local efficiency gains, there was no overall systemic efficiency gain across central government. So, there's a bit of a question mark against that promise. 1991, I'm amazed to find myself standing here, as a kind of apologist for the citizen's charter, because again, this is the only one where you can say "Well, yes actually, this did happen". The citizen's charter may well not have been the only thing pushing it to happen. I was somewhat involved in research around that at the time, and yes. It was easy to make fun of it, but there was, some kind of a shift, during that decade, during the nineties, and having targets and getting more information became, if not universal, at least, the norm. And far more widespread than it had been ten years earlier. So maybe, on that one. 1999. Joined-up government. Evidence-based policy making partnerships, e-government enhanced.. It was a bit of a pot pourri. As for joined-up government, it's hard to read the, endless, and ever-more detailed accounts of the relationship between the Chancellor of the Exchequer and the Prime Minister as a sterling example of joined-up government. And it's hard to read, the various accounts which have emerged to the so-called sofa-based policy making, as indicative of, very heavily, evidence linked, policy making. But certainly, some interesting documentation came out. The Cabinet Office produced some very nice, neat guides as to how to do it, Whether they actually did it? Very hard to say. 2011: Obviously, much too soon to make a judgement about that. Quite interesting in the way in which, the meaning of some of the terms, seem to shift in that white paper, so, equality seemed to take on a new kind of meaning, and, plurality seems to take on a new kind of meaning, meaning competition and contracting out. But we won't go into that. As for outcomes, we just don't know yet. So, the obvious question is "why?", if I'm even half-way right about this, that we've had a generation of massive change, undoubtedly costly in time and effort, and to some extent, in money. And all this was done without any very clear targets. Without any costings. And without any follow through to check. That's quite surprising! How could that be? Why would that be? Well let's look at some reasons why there was so little hard evidence. I'd say there's two, big, obvious groups of reasons. One.. And this is not the fault of Blair, or Thatcher, or Heath, or anybody else, t's just damned difficult, to design and implement, monitoring evaluation for big, complex reforms of this kind, for a whole raft of reasons which many people have written about. Including myself. The reforms, themselves, do not stand still. You don't take a model and implement it. What happens is that the model changes, in the process of implementation. The process of implementation usually takes, at least a year or two. And the context also changes, as you are going through the process, so that the thing that eventually gets implemented is not exactly, and sometimes not at all, the thing that you thought you were going to implement at the beginning. It's a moving picture. Even if you do an evaluation, even if you set one up. You have to set it up theoretically. In orthodox terms you have to set it up before you make the change, so that you've got before and after measurements, and that's often very difficult to do, both politically and even administratively. And then afterwards, even if you manage to collect some data on changes and outcomes, you usually have great difficulty attributing them, to that specific reform. Or, if you thought you could attribute something, to let's say the modernising government programme of 1999, how on Earth would you know which bit of that pot pourri it was that was actually the crucial bit? Or which two bits? Or which three bits? Because it's unlikely that the whole thing had, some kind of combined positive effect. It's much more likely that some things worked and some things doesn't. This is the whole realistic evaluation tradition, of Tilley and Pawson. That's the language I'm using at the moment. So there are big, methodological problems, even if, academics had got huge grants to do evaluations and we'd been able to have access and to be independent it would still have been, rather difficult to do. However, the second group of reasons. coming on top of the first, is the, the reason I've already mentioned. That, on the whole, The Whitehall elite seem to have been remarkably uninterested in doing this kind of evaluation. Anyway, political interest seldom sustained over the whole life-cycle of a major reform. Even if the government, the same government, is still in power, individuals will have moved on. In some cases, evaluations are actively resisted. I was around in the late 1980s, well, no, 1990 it would have been, trying to get grants to, trying to get research grants from the SRC to look at the impact of the 'working for patients' white paper, on the organization of the NHS. And at one point, my dear colleague, Steve Harrison, and I were, in the department of health, and, how shall I say, it was made clear to us that messages had been received, that academic attention, to the impact of these reforms, was not welcome. It was considered premature, and the idea was, the reforms should be allowed to settle down before anyone did any. Now that didn't stop some academics from doing work. But it certainly handicapped them from doing it, because the access was difficult, funding was difficult, and they were doing it all retrospectively. When the reform was already half over, so to speak. And that was a huge, the largest organization, and the most complex organization in Europe, barring, some people say, the Red Army, which was still in existence then. Unprecedented, kind of internal market reform, which had never been tried anywhere. Crying out for some sort of evaluation? No. Not necessary. We know it's right. So sometimes the evaluation is just not thought about. Sometimes the evaluation is actually resisted. Even if you have them, politicians tend not to wait for the results, until you move on to the next thing. I'll give you a quote. It's from a personal correspondence, from a permanent secretary, who was very heavily involved in the the Major and Blair reforms. And he wrote this, "governments lack a theory of.." "..and experience of.." "..embedding change coherently.." "..so the people involved and the storylines.." "..the people involved and the storylines.." "..are dropped and changed too quickly". The same person, informed me that in his view, two years after the 1999 'modernising government' white paper, basically, the prime minister and his entourage, and senior minsters, were no longer interested in that agenda at all. Their public service reform ideas had moved on. Us academics, hadn't even started publishing on it. You know, we were getting very excited, but up there, at the summits of power, it was already something.. Yes. It wasn't rejected, No. There was nothing wrong with it. Yes. It wasn't rejected, No. There was nothing wrong with it. It's just not interesting anymore. It's history, as they say. So there are two groups of reasons, now.. Why has there been so much reform then? One might ask. To some extent, this has been an international wave. And we are not alone. But I would like to argue that there is a degree of UK exceptionalism in this for reasons that I'll briefly describe. First of all we're in the Anglo-Saxon club, of enthusiasts for managerialism. So that includes Australia, New Zealand. US is an interesting case, because they talk the talk, but they don't walk the walk at all because they have constitutional and problems with the legislature, and with all sorts of vested interests, that cramp the president's style, if he wants to reorganise anything. And many of the American departments are the same as they were 20 years ago. They haven't been serially reorganised. But they talk the talk. They certainly have the managerialist, language. And a lot of their procedures and processes are quite managerialist. But we have to remember, and those of you who've looked at, any of my work over the last 15 years, will be bored with hearing me say and write this. We have to remember that the Anglo-Saxon club of which we are a leading member, is not the whole world. And that there are many, important, complexed, advanced, states out there, who really have not been so dramatically interested in this. Or they've pretended, and offered a polite interest, but they've never really tried to implement anything. Or they have been constitutionally, procedurally unable to implement things, even if they wanted to. Like, in Germany, the slim state debate raged for about seven or eight years, but actually didn't do very much, because they couldn't. The federal government remained very, very stable and similar, because it would have required, very difficult legislative processes to change it. So we're a member of, well first of all we're a member of a club of enthusiasts about management change. And secondly, we're probably the most.. We're the outlying member of that club. We have certain things that encourage management reform. Or I should say, repetitive management reform. We have those things to a greater degree, than anybody else. First of all, we're law-lite, We don't have a constitution that, restrains prime ministers, who want to make changes to the machinery of government, very much at all. The actual legal procedures, are extremely light and easy. And as long as you have a majority in the House of Commons, and you probably don't even need that. I've told academics and civil servants from other countries that the whole of the next steps programme, of agency creation from 1988 to the late 1990s that shifted at one point nearly 70% of the non-industrial civil service, out of ministries, into agencies or out of something, including ministries, into agencies. The whole of that programme, was carried through with basically no new legislation. They can't believe it. But surely you have to have a new statute when you create you know, the prisons agency, or the driving and vehicles licensing agency. No you don't. You don't. So it's a highly centralised, majoritarian systems, so.. What the prime minister decides, usually goes. for management reform. And it's a toothless legislature. Apologies to parliamentarians among you. But as far as management reform is concerned it's an absolutely toothless legislature. And believe me, I've sat in the libraries in the old days you actually had libraries with copies of Hansard in. And I've gone through the very few commons and lords debates that there have been, on management reform, and they are feeble in the extreme. Some very good points made by individual speakers. But it doesn't matter. It doesn't stop anybody for one minute. So my conclusion is, we have a lot of management reform, because it's so easy. If you are a prime minister and you want to use it for symbolic purposes, for a little exercise of rhetoric, to show you're in charge. To show you're doing something. Or maybe there's been a crises or a scandal, so let's reorganise. It's as easy as pie. This is the easiest country in the world, to make those sorts of changes in. As far as I know. Somebody will now stop to talk to me about, how easy it is in Bogotá or something but, as far as I know it's [indistiguishable] as this country in the world. So. Some reflections. I think, behind this process, I would not assume, that the motives for reform have remained absolutely constant over the 40 year period. I think there has been some shift. The way I would describe the shift, is as follows.. In the late 1960s and early 1970s, we were just coming to the end of a period in which machinery of government changes were really rather dry and dusty things. They were not things for popular public debate, or making big claims, or anything. They were just the government, adjusting its own administrative machinery. And you had, a little machinery of government secretariat, in the treasury, or the civil service department. And occasionally, you had to make machinery changes because bits of Whitehall were working very badly together. Occasionally, you wanted to make changes because because you had an awkward minister who needed a bigger department. The famous case of Richard Crossman, leading to the creation, of the department of health and social security. Because, either health OR social security would have been too small, for a minister of his eminence at that time. Things like that. Sometime during the 80s and 90s however, public management reform became something rather different. It became a more programmatic, and a more international thing. It became, like a kind of stage, on which you strutted to show that you were modern and progressive and that you knew, what the latest tools and processes were. Or even, in some cases, that you had invented them. And, public management reform in a number of countries, not just the UK, has now become a policy sector in its own right. People like Michael Barzelay have written about this at some length. So that it would be strange, for a party that thought it might be in government, after an election, nowadays, not to have some kind of programme of public management reform. Somehow, from somewhere, we've acquired the assumption, "Yes. Of course. But what will you do about public management reform. If you get power?". "Well, we'll do this..". That wasn't, really.. It certainly wasn't there in the 1950s. Maybe Harold Wilson had a bit of it in 1964. but if you go back, that's not normally part of manifestos. Very little was usually said. To put it another way, public management reform has become both an ideology and a business. A large scale, international business with its own networks and communities, that benefits considerably from this unceasing process of reform. According to the national audit office for example in the financial year 2003/2004, how much do you think this central government spent on management consultants, looking at the machinery of government? Answer. Just over two billion pounds. In one financial year. The national audit office also discovered the interesting fact that the, rising and falling of, expenditure on management consultants, almost, exactly, mirrored the private sector, corporate spending on management consultants, so when, private sector spending went down, because there was an economic recession, or something, public spending went up. so the big management consultancies were able to maintain a fairly steady flow of income, it just came from public sources instead of private sources sometimes. And people like Saint-Martin, "Saint-Martin" (French accent), I should say, I think, and others have, have written about, the nature of this emerging international community, and its links with management consultancies, OECD, World Bank, and various other intergovernmental organisations. Can this situation that I've described, if you believe it, can it change? Well, yes. I think a number of conditions might lead to its decay or even disappearance. First of all regular coalition governments might make it a bit more difficult doing a kind of unilateral, structural changes that have been the norm, for the last generation. We'll see. Some political scientists, as you know, think that we're likely to get coalitions, fairly regularly, in future. Others don't think that at all. So we'll have to wait and see. But that could blunt it. Growing public cynicism might reduce the symbolic, short-term gains of announcing, yet another reform. I'm sort of a little bit doubtful about that mechanism myself because I think, on the whole, it washes over the public even if they see any information about it at all. It's not headlines in The Sun, It doesn't usually get on the television news, or if it does, it's not the first item. And I guess most people have been taking it with a pinch of salt for quite a long time anyway. The white papers are directed at parliament, but parliament has no role in this process. This is a very strange sort of process. The whole process is bizarre to me. Governments could pass, some kind of self-denying ordinance. They could say, "OK in future we will only change the machinery of government.." "..only change departments who introduce major management reforms.." "..in statutory form" Or "We will never do it without introducing.." "..a costing" like you have on any other kind of bill how much will this cost? And, without specifying targets, and without having it audited each year for the next five years they could do something like that I see no sign of them doing it. It would be a rather unusual piece of government action to make things more difficult for themselves without there being a strong reason for it. So on the whole, my hunch, and it's no more than that, is that, in the near future the probability of major change, in this particular area of, central government management reform is quite low. The current situation, the situation that has been going on for, more or less, four decades, seems to me likely to go on for a little bit longer. And so finally, it's not much of a joke, but I'll say it anyway.. Promises continue to be plentiful, even if they're not cheap. Thank you. APPLAUSE

Early life and family

Tilley's father had died before he was born. His mother was Elizabeth Fraser, daughter of Thomas Fraser of Lane Son & Fraser (sometimes spelt 'Frazer').[1][2][3] He was educated privately at Bromley, Kent.[1][3][4]

Career

Tilley entered the service of the General Post Office on 11 February 1829[5] as a clerk in the Secretary's Office in Lombard Street, London,[3] having been nominated by a friend of his mother, the then Secretary, Francis Freeling, and appointed to the Secretary's office by the Postmaster General, the Duke of Manchester.[6]

He remained with the Post Office throughout his working life, rising from clerk to Secretary, the position he held on his retirement at the age of sixty-seven in 1880.[1]

In 1838, at the relatively young age of 27, and after only ten years with the Post Office, Tilley was appointed Surveyor of the Northern District of England on the nomination of the then Secretary of the Post Office, Colonel Maberly,[1] while the Appointment Books show that he was formally appointed on 25 October 1838 by the Postmaster General, the Earl of Lichfield.[7]

Tilley spent ten years as Surveyor of the Northern District of England, moving to Lytham (now known as Lytham St. Annes), Lancashire where he organised the distribution of mail[3] until on 29 September 1848 he was promoted to the position of Assistant Secretary of the Post Office.[8] Tilley's wife Cecilia was at that time suffering from consumption,[9] and brief mention is made of the sad family circumstances Tilley was experiencing at this time, which made him happy to return to London.[1]

Despite this, Tilley was involved in the organisation of The Great Exhibition held in Hyde Park, London in 1851.[10]

In 1854 a Commission of Enquiry into the establishment of the Post Office was set up which brought about a number of changes in the London establishment. The Postmaster General of the day, Lord Canning, sent Tilley to Edinburgh and Dublin to revise the establishments there. Tilley is credited with having ensured that the clerks, sorters and postmen received better pay.[1]

Tilley had been a great supporter of the Savings Bank Act (1861). This enabled the Post Office to offer savings accounts to less wealthy citizens with more security than banks could offer,[1] resulting in the present-day National Savings and Investments.

In 1864, when Sir Rowland Hill vacated the position of Secretary of the Post Office, Tilley was appointed to succeed him.[11] However, this appears to be contradicted by the existence of a letter dated 8 August 1860 which suggests that Tilley had been appointed Secretary earlier.[12]

Throughout Tilley's time at the Post Office, his close friendship with his brother-in-law, Anthony Trollope, continued.[11] In 1888, Trollope described Tilley as one of his "oldest and dearest friends".[11]

On 16 April 1880, at the age of 67, Tilley retired from the Post Office.[1][3] He was described by a colleague, Edmund Yates, in his Recollections and Experiences as a "shrewd, caustic and clever man, bred in the Post Office service and knowing it thoroughly; by no means a crocheteer, but with his public office experience, tempered by plenty of worldly knowledge, and as unimpressionable as an oyster"[1] Further description of his "remarkable" personality is given by one of Tilley's oldest official friends, but unidentified by name, who described him as "a hard man in official relations, yet genial. He was truthful, courageous and unaffected, generally a sound judge of character, and always ready to admit and correct a mistake. He was clear sighted, just and absolutely fearless, with a strong sense of duty; always wanting to do right."[1]

Charitable and public work

Sir John Tilley dedication in St Saviour, Pimlico

Having retired from the Post Office, Tilley did not retire from public life. For fifteen years he was a member of the Board of Guardians of St George's, Hanover Square, of which he became vice-chairman and later chairman. He also chaired the Relief Committee, engaged in the distribution of outdoor relief to the deserving poor, and the Fulham Road Workhouse Committee, responsible for the care and conduct of one of the largest workhouses in the country.[1]

He was a Manager and member of the finance committee of the Metropolitan Asylums Board,[2] a Manager of the West London Schools,[2] and in 1891 Chairman of the Eastern Hospital, during an Inquiry into maladministration at the hospital.[2]

He was also Treasurer of the Metropolitan Convalescent Institution, in which he took a special interest, and was also a Justice of the Peace for London and Middlesex.[1][2]

In January 1889, Tilley was nominated to the first London County Council.[2]

For many years, he was one of the churchwardens of St Saviour, Pimlico, in St George's Square, while the Rev. Henry Washington was vicar.[1] There, on 18 December 1898, a window was dedicated in his memory.[2]

Marriages and children

On 4 February 1839 Tilley married Cecilia Frances Trollope at St Mary's, Bryanston Square. Marriage record in parish register of St Mary's Church, Bryanstone Square[2][9] She was the daughter of Thomas Anthony Trollope and of Frances Trollope[9] and the sister of Anthony Trollope.[9][11]

They had five children, of whom only one survived to adulthood.[9][13]

  1. Frances Trollope Tilley (1839–1851)[3][14]
  2. Cecilia Isabel Tilley (1840–1850)[3][14]
  3. Ann Jane Tilley (1842–1850)[3]
  4. Arthur William Tilley (1845–1850)[3]
  5. Edith Diane Mary Tilley (1846–1925)[15][16]

John and Cecilia Tilley lived for a number of years at Carlton Hill, Penrith,[9] having purchased the property from Cecilia's mother.[10] When they returned to London in 1848, they lived at Allen Place where Cecilia Tilley died on 4 April 1849.[3][10][17]

Sir John Tilley & Arthur Augustus Tilley

On 18 May 1850, Tilley married secondly, at Kensington, Mary Anne Partington, the daughter of Thomas Partington[2] and of Penelope Ann Trollope, so a first cousin of Cecilia Frances Trollope.[18] They had one child, Arthur Augustus Tilley (1851–1942), a Classical scholar who became a lecturer in Roman History at King's College, Cambridge, and a historian.[1]

Mary Anne Tilley died 3 weeks after the birth of their son in 1851,[3] and on 7 February 1861 Tilley married thirdly Susannah Anderson Montgomerie, the daughter of William Eglinton Montgomerie of Annick Lodge and Greenville, Ayrshire, by his marriage to Susanna Fraser Anderson, and a granddaughter of Alexander Montgomerie.[2][4] in Kilmarnock, Ayrshire.[3] They had three children:

  • Cecilia Montgomerie Tilley (1862–1868)[10]
  • William George Tilley (1863 – 28 June 1887)[19][20]
  • John Anthony Cecil Tilley (1869–1952), who joined the Foreign Office and became British Ambassador to Brazil and later Japan.[1]

Dame Susannah Anderson Tilley

Susannah Anderson Tilley nee Montgomerie

died on 4 March 1880.[21]

Death

Tilley's gravestone in Brompton Cemetery

After a long illness, Tilley died on 18 March 1898 at his home, 73 St George's Square, London, where he had lived since 1856.[1][2][10] He is buried in Brompton Cemetery, near Earl's Court in South West London, with his third wife, Susannah.

Honours

References

  1. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r A. M. Cunynghame, "Sir John Tilley, K.C.B" (St Martin's le Grand, July 1898), passim
  2. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k The Times Archive in online database (subscription required), accessed 16 May 2011
  3. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l Wiseman, W.G., The Trollopes, The Tilleys and the Penrith Connection in Transactions of the Cumberland & Westmorland Antiquarian & Archaeological Society, 3rd Series, Vol VII (Titus Wilson & Son, Kendal 2007), pp. 179–182
  4. ^ a b Edmund Burke, ed., Annual Register (Longmans Green & Co, 1899) p. 156
  5. ^ British Postal Service Appointment Books, 1737–1969 "John Tilley (1)" in online database Ancestry (subscription required), accessed 22 July 2011
  6. ^ British Postal Service Appointment Books, 1737–1969 John Tilley (2), accessed 22 July 2011
  7. ^ British Postal Service Appointment Books, 1737–1969, John Tilley (3), accessed 22 July 2011
  8. ^ British Postal Service Appointment Books, 1737–1969, John Tilley (4), accessed 22 July 2011
  9. ^ a b c d e f Frances Eleanor Trollope, Frances Trollope: Her Life and Literary Work from George III to Victoria, vol. I (R. Bentley and Son, 1895), passim [1]
  10. ^ a b c d e Victoria Glendinning, Trollope (Hutchinson, London, 1992) passim
  11. ^ a b c d Anthony Trollope, Anthony Trollope's Autobiography (George Munroe, New York, 1888), passim
  12. ^ letter dated 8 August 1860 at Post Office Heritage
  13. ^ Joseph Hillis Miller, Others (Princeton University Press, 2001), p. 87
  14. ^ a b 1841 Census
  15. ^ 1861 Census
  16. ^ Principal Probate Registry, Calendar of the Grants of Probate and Letters of Administration made in the Probate Registries of the High Court of Justice in England
  17. ^ Brenda Ayres, Frances Trollope and the Novel of Social Change (Greenwood Press, 2002), p. 17
  18. ^ R. H. Super, The Chronicler of Barsetshire: A Life of Anthony Trollope (University of Michigan Press, 1988), p. 55
  19. ^ 1871 Census
  20. ^ Principal Probate Registry, Calendar of the Grants of Probate and Letters of Administration made in the Probate Registries of the High Court of Justice in England 1861–1941: William George Tilley, in online database Ancestry (subscription required), accessed 3 May 2011
  21. ^ Principal Probate Registry, Calendar of the Grants of Probate and Letters of Administration made in the Probate Registries of the High Court of Justice in England 1861–1941: Susannah Anderson Tilley in online database Ancestry (subscription required), accessed 3 May 2011
  22. ^ Sir John Tilley at Post Office Heritage web site
  23. ^ Letter regarding John Tilley's Knighthood at Post Office Heritage web site
This page was last edited on 31 July 2023, at 17:31
Basis of this page is in Wikipedia. Text is available under the CC BY-SA 3.0 Unported License. Non-text media are available under their specified licenses. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc. WIKI 2 is an independent company and has no affiliation with Wikimedia Foundation.