To install click the Add extension button. That's it.

The source code for the WIKI 2 extension is being checked by specialists of the Mozilla Foundation, Google, and Apple. You could also do it yourself at any point in time.

4,5
Kelly Slayton
Congratulations on this excellent venture… what a great idea!
Alexander Grigorievskiy
I use WIKI 2 every day and almost forgot how the original Wikipedia looks like.
Live Statistics
English Articles
Improved in 24 Hours
Added in 24 Hours
What we do. Every page goes through several hundred of perfecting techniques; in live mode. Quite the same Wikipedia. Just better.
.
Leo
Newton
Brights
Milds

Seniority in the Parliament of Malaysia

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is a complete list of members of the Parliament of Malaysia based on seniority as of 13 September 2018.

YouTube Encyclopedic

  • 1/5
    Views:
    333 707
    810
    21 697
    648
    22 670
  • Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea | Mark Blyth | Talks at Google
  • Protecting human rights and preserving civil liberties: The role of courts in a democracy.
  • Last Stand At Saratoga
  • James Merralls Fellowship in Law Lecture 2019: Professor Arun Thiruvengadam
  • 13 August 2018 - The Hindu Editorial News Paper Analysis - [UPSC/SSC/IBPS] Current affairs

Transcription

BORIS DEBIC: Welcome everybody. I am extremely pleased to welcome today Mark Blyth. Mark Blyth will share with us his insights into austerity as it takes shape in the European Union. Let me read a little bit from his biography. Mark Blyth is a faculty fellow at the Watson Institute, professor international political economy in Brown's political science department, and director of the university's Undergraduate Programs in Development Studies and International Relations. He's also the author of "Great Transformations-- Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the 20th Century." He's the editor of the "Routledge Handbook of International Political Economy," co-editor of a volume on constructivist theory on political economy titled "Constructing the International Economy," and he's working also on a new book that questions the political and economic sustainability of liberal democracies, called "The End of the Liberal World." That's dramatic. Blyth is a member of the Warwick Commission on International Financial Reform. He is a member of the editorial board of the "Review of International Political Economy." And his articles have appeared in journals such as "The American Political Science Review," "Perspectives in Politics," "Comparative Politics," and "World Politics." He has a Ph.D. in political science from Columbia University, and taught at Johns Hopkins University from 1997 to 2009. Please give a hand to Mark Blyth. MARK BLYTH: Thank you. Cheers. Is this mic on? Yes? Can you hear me? Hello? Right. So I have a Scottish accent. There's surprise number one. And those slides started to change themselves, which is surprise number two. OK, how am I going to start this? Why did I write this book? I wrote this book for the following reason-- I got really, really pissed off with people with lots of money telling people who don't have any money they need to pay shit back. That's basically it. I grew up on the butt end of the British welfare state. I'm an orphan, and I was raised by my paternal grandmother. So I am the greatest living example of inter-generational social mobility you're ever going to see, because I'm a freaking Ivy League professor. So I went from there to there. How did I do that? Because of this thing that gets blamed called the welfare state, that bloated, paternalist, out of control, incentivizing, demotivating piece of crap called the welfare state. Now, why is this a completely bullshit story? Well, that's not, but why does it turn into a bullshit story? It turns into a bullshit story for the following reason-- back in 2000, the number one concern of financial markets globally was there wasn't going to be enough federal debt, because we had balanced the budget. Seriously, the number one concern was there wouldn't be enough T-bills. So fast-forward 13 years, ah, we're all freaking out. Now, in between, a couple interesting things happened. So you have a balanced budget, which basically means over time, as the economy grows, your debt stock is going to shrink. And that's why people had a problem with it. So you're going through a period of rapid growth. This was the tech boom period, all this sort of stuff. And then there's 9/11. So there's a little dip in the economy and a guy called Greenspan comes along and says, let's cut interest rates and essentially do asset protection for everybody who has bought assets by giving them more or less free money. So then we decide on top of that we're going to have two tax cuts. Why? Because we just need more money. Screw it. We're just going to do it. Let's have some tax cuts. No corresponding way of paying it off, or whatever, we'll just take the tax cuts. And then we'll decide to fight two wars of choice for dubious political reasons without raising any taxes. That'll be a good one. So by the time you get to 2006, there's 61% debt to GDP already. I don't remember anybody in Congress, particularly Republicans, jumping up and down about the crazy level of federal debt in 2006. And then in 2007 and 2008, there's a run on the repo markets. Basically, the hidden story of the financial crisis that nobody really talks about-- it's actually quite simple-- is that because there was a shortage of T-bills, because, in fact, many of them were in China, because they keep buying a lot of them, we started to use AAA mortgage products as collateral for short term financial deals in the repo markets. As the housing crisis happened, those bonds that made up those instruments fell from AAA to B to C. At that time, that meant that if you were a heavily leveraged financial organization-- a Bear Sterns, for example-- and you were using these things as pledges and as repo collateral, as they fell in value, you had to use more and more of them to borrow the same amount of money. Unfortunately, you couldn't do that, because there's a fixed stock of the assets. And they're hugely levered. This meant a 3% return against their asset base, rendered them effectively insolvent. Once everybody figured this out, you shout fire in a crowded theater, everybody freaks out, heads for the exits. You get a liquidity crunch. You've got a financial crisis. We decided to bail out the system rather than let it fail, because it was too big to fail. The costs of doing so were basically a 30% drop in tax revenue across the OECD countries, because the financial sector had become so big, particularly in the United States and the United Kingdom, that it was generating huge amounts of taxes. At the same time, the economy slows down as the liquidity crunch hits the real economy and affects lending and borrowing and spending. Consumer expenditures trend down, as do consumer expectations, as do investment expectations. You get caught in a slump. Once you get caught in a slump, automatic transfers in the economy mean that benefits go up at the same time as tax revenues go down. So you're going to have a bigger deficit. As you have a bigger deficit, you multiply that over time, you issue more debt, you go from 61% to 100% debt to GDP. That's why we're here. There was no orgy of public spending. It's a lie. I take Amtrak every day. I would've noticed an orgy of public spending. If there was an orgy on public spending, it was on asset protection and income protection for the people who had made out with the most for the past 30 years when we bailed out those assets. That's actually what happened. Now, here's the inequity of the [INAUDIBLE] in this whole thing-- why is it that social security, which isn't even part of federal budget calculations on the deficit, which, by the way, has a $2.3 trillion surplus, that has to be cut so we can pay back the debt accrued by bailing out some of the richest people in our society and ensuring their assets? Does anybody else think that's total horse shit? Because I really do, and that's why I wrote this book. Now, here's the weird thing. We're actually not in that much of a mess. It's been a sticky recovery. It's been a technological shock to a lot of service jobs that we didn't expect, et cetera. But nonetheless, we haven't been cutting them. Because of that, the federal deficit's projected to be around 3% next year-- even with a margin of error in the projection, say 4%. Britain has its own currency, like us, and has been cutting, been doing austerity. Having done that, it's now looking at 7%, totally [INAUDIBLE] growth, and a possible triple-dip recession. Europe has been cutting like there's no tomorrow. They've got the leaches on the corpse and they're opening up the veins. Greece has lost 30% of GDP in four years. The German army didn't manage that between '41 and '45. That's how much damage has been done by this. So the question is the following-- why is it that Europe, particularly the European Union, the part that we think of as the most kind of, if you will, welfare-statish-friendly transer, et cetera, suddenly became this huge doomsday device for this enormous experiment on austerity, which so far has cost around 30% of GDP in the periphery and has generated 25 million extra unemployed in comparison to the United States? Seems like something to investigate. So, there's a standard picture of Europe in terms of its fiscal balances. As you can see, the United States around here, 2012. By the way, always look at the net figure, because if you look at the gross figure, that assumes that nobody pays taxes. And given that we all just wrote checks just a little while ago, that would tell you that you really shouldn't look at that one. It also it seems the country has no assets. And if that's the case, why do we have the National Security Investment Act to stop people buying assets? So obviously, look at the net one. So you look at the net one, where are you? Well, basically, everybody's kind of in the mire, more or less. So what brought about this fine mess? Age check in the room. Anybody who's giggling now is over the age of 40. On the left, we have Laurel and Hardy, and on the right, we have Angela Merkel and Sarkozy. There we go. I put that in purely for comedic values, just to make sure everyone is paying attention. And actually, they did bring about this fine mess, so that is a serious point. So what's the story here? Well, there's an official story. It's what I call story one, and this is the sort of vaguely sophisticated version that you get if you read things like "The Economist," "The Financial Times," et cetera, et cetera. And I'm going to tell you why it's total crap, because it's not really true at all. So there's story one and story two. So here's the official story, story one. You do this by looking at this. This is interest rate convergence over 10 year bond spreads. So if you go back in the day before there was this thing called the Euro, when everybody had their own currency, if you were buying a bit of Greece on 10 years, there's a 25% risk premium you're getting paid for holding that. That means that basically there's a one in four chance they're going to default. Why would you price that in? Well, because they haven't run a budget surplus in 50 years. Because they've been taking turns to steal the state and using other people's rents and revenues to do it since they basically ended the Civil War, so why would you not price this at 25%? Then have a look at the French, the Italians, the rest of the Mediterranean, it's strained around 15%. This whole [INAUDIBLE] in here, over 10%. That's a lot. You're getting paid a lot for just holding a 10 year debt. Now, that reflects the real price of the bond, the real risk of default that's in the bond. Now, the official story goes like this-- around 1991 there was this wonderful treaty called the Maastricht Treaty. Well, that's '86. '91 is the Monetary Treaty. And we decided that we're going to build this monetary union in Europe. And what did that mean? It meant basically that you're going to have this German bank called the Bundesbank generalized across the whole area. All the people that currently have inflation and exchange rate risk and default risk no longer will have it because we're going to take away their printing presses. And once we've locked up all the printing presses in the one time deal and given them to a guy in Frankfurt, and he's the only one who can print the money, well, basically doesn't that mean that Greece becomes Germany? Doesn't that mean that Italy becomes Germany? Because after all, they can't inflate their way out of trouble. So you get rid of that risk. You can't devalue your way, which is a backdoor way of solving the same problem. All you can either do is deflate-- austerity-- which is politically unpalatable, or you basically sort your economy out and everybody kind of becomes German, and that's the great plan. And you can see how this is represented in this risk premium. There's where the Euro comes in. And then there's a 7 and 1/2 year period where basically all of these countries-- think about how diverse this is-- everyone from Belgium to Italy to Greece to Spain to Portugal have basically got exactly the same default risks. Now, that's kind of odd if you think about it for more than two minutes. So what's behind this? Well, the story goes like this. Basically, what's undermining this-- if you go back to the end here and you see where the spreads go up right, why does it all start to go wrong? Well, if you have a look here, your current account and balances, exports and imports. And you'll find that what you've got here is most countries in the Euro, the major countries, are basically running deficits all the way through. And the only one that starts to run a surplus here is Germany, which picks up just as the Euro comes in and becomes the export powerhouse. Now, when you control for the size of the German economy relative to everybody else, what you begin to realize is that their surplus is the counterpart everybody else's deficit. In other words, somebody has to buy all those BMWs. And if you're buying all those BMWs, you're not making your own [INAUDIBLE] and selling them back to the Germans. So you start to get these current account imbalances. But that begs the question-- where did all these guys in the south get the money to buy the BMWs in the first place? Well, that's your story about lax public finances. This is these countries that are spending too much. So look, it's the PIGS-- Ireland, Spain, Greece, Portugal. The Netherlands we'll put in a bracket, right? But basically, look-- a huge amount. That's 10% year on year annual growth of government expenditure. They are spending like drunken sailors, there's no doubt about this. Now, what made this possible? As I said before, this is the ECB, being Deutschbank Uber Alles, taking inflation and devaluation risk off the table. And also, the Maastricht criteria for Euro gives credible rules against sovereign misbehavior. You can have a 60% debt load, 3% deficit, and variable inflation. And as I said, the yields converge, and the countries over-borrow. As we saw in those last three slides, they're basically spending too much money. But then what does that do to your competitiveness? Well, it's going to obviously hit your competitiveness. If you're spending that much money and you've got a huge trade imbalance, you've got to be basically awarding yourself way above productivity wage increases. And look at what you've got. Ireland, Spain, Italy, Greece, Cyprus, Malta, Portugal. The PIGS again. And look at these massive labor cost changes over the last 7 year period. You're awarding yourself pay increase you can not hope to cash. So this is all a very convincing story, right? And what made this possible? Well, of course, what made it possible is cheap debt. Because as those yields converge, look what's happening. Portugal is borrowing. Spain is borrowing. Greece is borrowing. Ireland is borrowing. Look who's actually in surplus. The Germans and the Netherlands. So their savings are financing their consumption. So these countries have massively over-borrowed. With the take-home being the southern countries have borrowed too much. Now, have a look at this network diagram. It's kind of interesting, because there's a question mark there for a reason. There's Portugal. Relative sizely economy 123 billion euros. Spain, 345. Italy, very big-- nearly half a trillion. But pretty much all of their bonds are domestically held. 60% are long-term domestic. The ones that are 10-year rollover escalate by 10%. Look at this. Look who's popped up here, with a trillion dollars of crap assets lying on their balance sheet. It's the Brits, the world's largest financial entrepot. And look who's up here. It's those prudential Germans, who save a lot and tell everyone to upgrade their scales. They've got half a trillion of debt going on. So what do you mean the southern countries have borrowed too much? There's a rather large problem with this story. You can't have over borrowing with over lending. This is actually a Citibank advertisement. Some of you who are over the age of 16 may remember this. The largest ever advertising campaign for a finance company in the world was Citi's campaign, "live richly," from 2003 to 2006. It didn't invite you to save up money. It didn't invite you to be prudential. It said live richly. It didn't even say be rich. You kind of have to have rich before you spend it unless you've just got a giant line of credit. So let's run that story again. Here's the greatest moral hazard trade in human history. Remember the whole story I told you about the ECB and credibility and all the rest of it? Here's why it's complete horse shit. Because what actually happened was this-- I'm a large European bank. I know that I've got a sovereign behind me that, if I become really big, I'll become too big to fail. Which basically gives me a license for doing whatever the hell I want because then it will all be bailed. It gives me a funding cost advantage, and it means that basically I can lever up well beyond human reason with pretty much no consequences. And the more powerful I become, the bigger threat I am to that sovereign. And eventually, if the sh-- hits the fan, well, you know, I'll get bailed out. It's totally fine. So imagine I know there's this thing called the Euro coming in, and you're all other European banks, and you know that you could earn a nice little bit of coupon buying this Greek bond at 25%. There aren't that many of them-- it's a thinly traded market. But if you can get it, if you lose, fine. But the upside's great-- 25%. Now, what happens if everybody really believes this Euro story and everybody starts to converge down? Well, I'm going to make less and less money on those bonds over time. So a quick bit of math up in your head. How would you make even more money on a declining spread? You've go to use volume, you've got to use leverage. So what you do is you basically get the balance sheet of your bank and you cram it with as much periphery debt as you possibly can. You take all your nice, safe German, Dutch bonds and you throw them out. And you pile on as much Greek debt and as much Portuguese debt and as much French debt as you can. And you turbo charge that, running operating leverage of around 40 to 1, which means your equity cushion is less than 3% percent of your asset footprint. You make Lehman Brothers look like a prudentially run organization. And you do this because you've got a guarantee. The guarantee is the state. The state will come and rescue you. You get in trouble, you're fine. Except there's a slight flaw in the plan. What happens when the Euro comes in? You have to give up your printing press. So that means your state can't bail you out anymore. Well, that's even better. Because then I become a systemic risk. I'm not just a risk to France, I become a risk to the entire European banking system. Score! I've got the ECB over a bottle. I can do whatever I want because they're going to have to bail me. Except it's run by Jurgen Stark and a bunch of Germans. And they're not going to bail you. So when the shit hits the fan, you've got a really, really big problem. Which is where we are now. Core banks get stuffed with periphery debts gone bad, a result of over landing. Foreign banks consolidated claims on Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain in 2011, last time they published any reliable figures. French banks have over 33% of GDP equivalent on their balance sheets in periphery assets that aren't coming back anytime soon. Add in the Spanish real estate loans they've got on there-- run. And you have a SocGen account. Netherlands, one bank, ING, 211% of GDP is its asset footprint. Leverage ratio is over 40 to 1. That alone is 30% of Dutch GDP. They don't have a printing press anymore. Are you beginning to see the problem? The result is assets held by banks in Germany, France, and the UK are about double the annual GDP of the entire EU. Here's the too big to fail USA. Top six bank assets, 61% of GDP. Any one of them fails, even allowing for systemic interconnections, you're going to take out 10% of US GDP. That's about $1.4 trillion, $1.5 trillion. That's a lot, but when you've got your own currency, you've got the global reserve asset, we can deal with that. We can bail it. We've done it. That's what we did. It cost of a $3 trillion all told, that's it. We're now in recovery mode. At least the Brits have their own currency. There's British GDP. That's the size of their banks. You should be very, very afraid now. Now let's have a look at this one. Here's France. BNP Paribas, Agricole, Generale. These three banks alone are taking you up to 250% of GDP, and they don't have a printing press, and they're seriously impaired with bad assets. And now here's the kicker. You know that ECB? It's a fake central bank. It's really a currency board. Because what it does is it says, we're not doing bond buying, we're not mutualizing debt, you have to look after the problem yourself. So when you have a financial crisis, you've got four exists. You can either inflate-- whoops, you don't have a printing press. You can devalue-- whoops, don't have your own currency. Or you can do austerity. You can squeeze and hope you stabilize public finances, add liquidity, keep the can kicking down the road-- this is LTROs, all the loans that have been given to the banks. But at the end of the day, you cannot do a Bernanke. So what's a Bernanke? A Bernanke is when you go into the banking system and you grab the shitty assets on their books and you put them on the Federal Reserve's balance sheet. And you call them things like Maiden Lane 2, and the Termloan Auction Facility 3, and a bunch of completely opaque nonsense that nobody will ever understand unless they spend time looking into this. Congress, who basically don't understand anything, are completely oblivious to what's going on-- you then flush the entire system out with as much liquidity as you can, and you allow them to recapitalize as they de-lever. Which is why the operational leverage of the American banks is now about 50 to 1 rather than 30 to 1 at the height of the crisis. They've rebuilt, they've recapitalized, they've cleaned their balance sheet. As the economy recovers, you know all those assets that you bought? Guess what? Those houses in Glendale one day will have value again, and you sell them back to the banks. It's not a money pump. It's an asset swap with liquidity. The ECB can't do that. It is constitutionally and intellectually incapable of making that move. Consequently, what the markets were pricing is as yields were spiking was the possibility of a breakup of the Euro. Because if any one of those banks goes down, it doesn't stop at Spain. It doesn't stop at France. It goes all the way back to the German banks. If that goes bad, it's game over for the core European banks, which is why we really have austerity policies. It's about stopping a bank run around the bond market. This is why you've got to keep the Greeks in at all costs. Because if you're a bank, and you've got 2% of your assets in Greek debt-- say you're exposed to Greece heavily. How are you going to get rid of that? Well, you can't. You can sell it on the hedge funds basically at 20% on the face value. Or you can hope it doesn't go bad. But imagine you wake up one day, and you think, this is going to go bad. You want to sell it, so you sell it first. The minute all those contracts hit the floor, what happens to the price? Everybody else dumps theirs and they go to the floor. You've now made a 2% loss to your portfolio. How do you balance it back? You sell the next asset class before it goes down. Hi, Portugal, how are you this morning? So you dump Portugal. And as those prices go to zero, what do you do? You look around and you go, shit, what have I got left? Let's dump the Irish, then. So you throw the Irish on the floor, prices go to zero. You've now knocked 11% of Euro-zone GDP and probably about 12% of your portfolio. You do that on the lending portfolio of a highly levered bank, what's going to happen to its share price once people figure out? So you're going to have a huge panic that's caused by a sovereign bank run, right the way through a currency union, something that is supposed to be theoretically impossible. That's what this has always been about. That's why you keep the Greeks in. That's why you're willing to destroy 30% of GDP. Because this is about saving Societe Generale, and it is about saving Deutsch Bank from their own over borrowing and over lending mistakes. Consequences. You can't solve a banking problem with budget cuts. You can cut Greek's public spending to Neolithic levels. It's not going to make a damn bit of difference to SocGen's balance sheet. You can't run a gold standard in a democracy. We tried this in the 1920s. It really didn't work too well-- ended up with a few political parties that were kind of nasty. You can't solve a solvency problem with a liquidity instrument. But God bless Mario, he's been trying. You just add enough liquidity and hope the problem goes away by saying, I'll do whatever it takes. That's what he said six months ago, the yields came down. Since then, he's actually done nothing, and yet the yields have gone down, proving one thing-- it's about the credibility of bank policy. It's not about cutting the budget. The markets aren't craving an extra 30,000 civil servants being thrown out of work in Greece. They're worried about the Euro breaking up. So once you give a credible guarantee, you do a Bernanke-lite, all of the market pressures are relieved. That was what was lacking the whole time. And the most important one is you can't all cut at once and expect to grow. Why not? Because in order to save, you need to have income from which to save. So if everybody simultaneously cutting, nobody's generating income. So imagine the economy with an 80% debt to GDP ratio, and turn it into a simple fraction of four over five. Now imagine that 40% of the five is government expenditure. You want to cut in half. You're really going to credibly commit to cut the budget. So you just turn that into four over four. On a constant stock a debt, your debt to GDP ratio just went from 0.8 to 1. Every single country that's undergone an austerity program now has more debt than when they started. Any country the hasn't cut, including the United States, now has proportionately less. The evidence is in. And the tragedy is it was all avoidable, and we knew this already. So why did anybody, especially in Europe, ever think this was a good idea? For that, you have to kind of have to go back in time. And it's still about two rival stories. This time it's not ECB credibility versus the moral hazard trade. It's something far more spooky. The first one I like call liberalism's emetic economics, emetic being a wonderful word meaning to throw up. And what's this all about throwing up. You go back to John Locke's "Treatise on Government." The fifth chapter is really fascinating. John Locke is this guy who's basically the intellectual propagandist of a bunch of guys who want to kill the king and take all the property for themselves. They're called the merchant classes, and these are the guys that then set up markets and land, labor, capital, private property, throw people off the land, all the rest of it. You ever heard the word vagabond? It means a man without bondage. Why bondage? Because basically, you've been thrown off your land, so you basically had your status removed from you. So basically, the English Revolution sets up the markets in private probably, et cetera. And then there's a problem, because the minute you do this, you recognize that untrammeled markets lead to massive income and wealth inequalities. Which is great if you happen to be the guy at the top of the pile, and not so great if you're at the bottom. So unfortunately, then you need a sate. Why do you need a state? To make markets, in the first place. The notion that they pop out of the ground fully formed is a nice fiction, but simply not true. In order to turn serfs into workers, you actually need acts of parliament and legislation. The state makes these things happen. But here's the kicker. You need to state to police the inequalities that the market makes possible. Because if you don't-- poor Adam Smith on this one-- "for every rich man"-- this is out of "The Wealth of Nations"-- "for every rich man, there must be 500 poor, and that rich man must sleep always with the strong arm of the civil magistrate at his side, for he is always regarded with jealousy and envy." So you need that state to police the inequality. But here's the Lockean kicker. This is why we have the Second Amendment. Any state strong enough to police those inequalities is strong enough to come and take your money. So you've got a dilemma running into this. You need this state, you can't live without it, but at the same time, you can't live with it, because you're afraid of the damn thing. So how are you going to do this? And how are you going to pay for it? Because most people don't want to pay any taxes. Well, that's where this guy comes in, David Hume. He has a wonderful essay on money and on interest. He talks about merchants being the most useful race of men, because when you give it to them, even though money's neutral in the long run, if you give it to him and his friends, it goes to the right places really fast. So basically, you think of money in a Keynesian way from Hume, which is short-term stimulus is long-run neutral, but really because you give it to my friends rather than losers. Now, what he comes up with is the problem with government debt. Liberalism loves debt, because, if you think about it, it's a free option for the state. So you're the state, I'm the merchant, I've got lots of inequality in my society-- I'm worried about people coming and burning my house down. So I say to you, you need to protect me. And you say, you need to pay me. And I say, I don't want to pay taxes. You say, ah, I have this thing called a debt instrument. It's fabulous. You go, how does that work? Well, it works like this. You give me a better paper, and I'll give you a million pounds. Brilliant. OK, what happens now? In 10 years time, I'll give you the million back, and I'll pay you interest. What are you going to say? So I'll lend you the money you need to protect me, and then you'll give me it back and you'll give me interest. Fabulous. It's a free option. Unlimited upside, zero downside. Problem. Original argument against it. Crowding out. In order for this to work, you're going to offer a rate of interest higher than the market would produce. So everybody goes in to government debt. Because of this, as Hume says, all the gold and silver necessary for commerce gets crowded out of the economy, finds its way into debt securities, the whole nation ends up in hock, eventually you have to sell yourself to foreigners, and you end up with a bankruptcy of the nation. So easy money and crowding out. The downside of debt means that it's an attractive way of paying for the state you need but you don't want, but at the same time, a terrifying one. Because at the end of the day, it's going to result in the ruin of the nation. Adam Smith picks up on this one. For him, it's all about why we actually save and invest, why x equals i in economics to this day. Savings equals investment. Why is this? Well, for him, it's because we're all parsimonious Scots, we're all hardwired to save. There's a wonderful line where he says, "where there is tolerable security, a man would be perfectly crazy if he did not employ as investment all his available capital." So basically, you take the money, you invest, it automatically produces economic growth. Well, he also recognizes this whole thing about inequality in the state. My favorite line from Adam Smith. "Civil government, insofar as it is instituted, is instituted for the defense of the rich against the poor, or for those who have property against those who have none." That is not Karl Marx. That is Adam Smith, end of Book Two of "The Wealth of Nations," quote, unquote. Now, he recognizes then that you're going to have to pay for this, so he goes to taxation. But the forward of "The Wealth of Nations" starts off with progressive taxes. It's totally nuts. So here, look, see the people who have got the most stuff? They have the most skin in the game. They should pay the most taxes. And then he goes, wait a minute-- that would mean the rich would pay the most taxes. Well, we can't have that. So then he backs off immediately and turns around and argues for exactly what the Republicans are arguing to do-- a national consumption tax on everything except luxuries. So your yacht is fine, but your corn flakes are going to be taxed. Problem with this. Well, it never raises enough revenue. And he recognizes that. So he's like, shit, what am I going to do? And he goes, I suppose there has to be debt. But the problem with debt is exactly as Hume's pointed out. Everybody's going to invest in the debt markets, the underlying economy is going to crumble. Because of that you'll end up with more debt on a smaller economy, and eventually the whole nation gets bankrupted. So what do you end up with? Debt perverting parsimony, therefore savings doesn't lead to investment doesn't lead to growth. All very convincing, and it's all exactly the same story as we hear now. Now, when you hear the same arguments repeated for 300 years without modification regardless of any facts in fact in them, you should generally be suspicious. The result is you can't live with it, can't live without it, don't want to pay for it. So I like to call this liberalism's neuralgia and the aspirin of austerity. You reach for it regardless of if it does you any good. But it's a 300-year-old trip. Now, how do we know that these guys are wrong about this? Well, basically, at the time they were writing, Hume predicted the collapse of the British economy by, I think it was, 1780. And in fact, what happened was they went from the relatively low debt levels that they had, but they were accumulating, all the way to the highest debt that they ever had, which was 240% of GDP at the end of the Napoleonic Wars. So never mind 80%, 100%, whatever. Back in the day, they had 240% debt to GDP at the end of 1815. What happened to the British economy after 1815 until 1914? It ran the hold goddamn world and expanded faster than anyone ever thought humanly possible. Reinhart and Rogoff 95%, my ass. Now, this creates two liberal stories that go through the 19th century. Story one, David Ricardo. You can't live with it, and you don't want to pay for it, and you pretend you don't need it. Second one. This is John Stuart Mill, handsome fellow. I know. Accepting the need for it, and also accepting the need to pay for it. Because if you don't pay for it, then you get into a problem, because if you basically leave the state out of the equation, you cannot rely on markets to do anything except the inequalities that will undermine markets in the long-run themselves. So you get these two very different versions of liberalism come out of this. This one goes to the Austrian economist. This one goes to the Keynesians. That's basically the way it splits down the middle. Now, along came the Great Depression. I love this picture. It's absolutely emblematic. It's one of my favorite slides of the Great Depression-- the bread line at the same time as the, no way like the American way. So reality, theory, facts, whatever. Now, here's the first one. I like to call this the emetic response, American liquidationism. This is Joseph Schumpeter. And by the way, he actually looked like that. This is not an exaggeration. He really did. And he, in the 1920s, had come over from Austria and basically taken up residence running Harvard's economics department. And the basic story was there's the long run capital structure of the economy, you can't really see it, you don't know what's going on, you should never intervene. What happens is that banks, there are booms and bust business cycles. Banks have a problem, particularly when the bank is backed by the government. They produce too much credit, entrepreneurs get confused about price signals, they invest in things they shouldn't, you end up producing things you're never going to need, the credit pump dries up, and eventually you have this purging that needs to happen. So you binge on credit and then you purge. This is version one of austerity. Because of this misallocation of capital because of credit, you end up with too much in the wrong type of investment in the capital structure. So you basically have the boom, and then you have to have the slump, and you have to go barf and you have to get it all out and let the clock reset, and off you go. Now, the British had a version of this, which, you know, of course, the British are a bit more polite than this, so they wouldn't be emetic. So they have the treasury view, which is a more austere response. And it's very similar, but again, it's these arguments from the 1700s brought back. So the basic idea is that free trade is welfare-enhancing. Well, the Brits would say that, because they were 50% of the global economy at that point in time, and most of their free trade was done with empire. But putting that to one side, I'm sure the Indians thought it was free trade when they showed up, and so did the Chinese. But anyway, 1910 to 1920s, this is Churchill when he was Chancellor of the Exchequer, the finance minister. He comes out with this memorandum written by a guy called Henderson that basically responds to a guy called Lloyd George's thing about, can we do something about unemployment? The problem had been this-- Britain's the largest economy in the world, World War I spanked 60% of its national wealth. They're on the gold standard. Basically, exchange rate clever mechanism for the global economy. They have a choice. If they go back on the gold standard with a high exchange rate, it protects all the people who hold sterling paper, because you're not devaluing their assets. If you go back on a low one, it benefits the domestic economy because you'll get an export boost and your domestic economy will go up. But all the people holding sterling paper will freak out because you've devalued their assets. So they'll dump them. So you've got a run on the pound and a run on the exchanges, so you're screwed either way. So what did they do? They went back on a high exchange rate. The result? An instant extra million unemployed that lasted for a decade. So that was one of the lynch pins in the global economy that caused the Great Depression. So lots of people are saying, can't we do anything about this? Can't we do something about unemployment? And along came the memorandum that says, no-- and there's an argument called Ricardian Equivalence-- and spending now is going to be zero sum against taxes in the future. So if you know that, the minute you do it, it nullifies its own effects, so don't even try it. Second thing, and this is particularly true on investment, if government presumes to do the job of the private sector, the private sector will let it do it, but then it will do it at a cost. Because it's still not investing, so it's zero sum against itself. And the last one you may remember from the Obama stimulus was the lack of shovel-ready projects. Remember that language? It's written in there-- it was called the lack of suitable public works. Now, here's the second story that comes out of the John Stuart Mill tradition. Basically, it's not about Keynes right in the general theory. There's a wonderful line by an economist called June Robinson. She says that, "in 1936, Keynes was writing down what might cause unemployment while Herr Hitler was curing it." There's a certain element of teaching birds how to fly here. And the two critical cases here were the Germans-- as it says here. There's a story that basically it was all sort of like Catholics in the south that voted for Germany. No it's not. They were industrial workers. They were miners. And then here's a guy called Takahashi Korekiyo, who is the guy who was the guru for the Japanese Central Bank's Abenomics policy at the moment of massive monetary and fiscal stimulus. So this is a guy from '34. So what actually happens here is very similar to what's going on in the Euro-zone. You have simultaneous contractions of the five largest economies in the world. Everybody cuts at once. GDP shrinks, constant stock of debt goes up. The British debt to GDP ratio in 1930 was 170%. By 1933, despite repeated rounds of cuts, it was 190%. It continued to go up. In Germany, what happened was, after short-term capital United States, post the '23 inflation, had made Germany the most stable and fastest growing economy in Europe at that point in time. There was a swap in the agreement governing war debts. The main war debts got seniority. The American capital pulled out to take advantage of the stock market boom in 1928, '29 and a federal interest rate increase. If you get 7% per sticking it in a bank, so why would you put it in Germany? A lot of capital goes flying out. To balance the budget, a guy called Bruning comes in as the chancellor, and he starts hacking away at the budget. So he issues somewhere in the region of about 200 emergency austerity decrees. At that point in time, there's a minor party that everyone had written off. They got 8% of the vote in 1928, or thereabouts. By 1930, it was up to I think 18%. By 1933, it had 43.3% of the vote. It was the only party arguing against austerity. I don't think I need to tell you what they were called. Japan was even worse. The brunt of civilian expenditures, the brunt of public expenditure cuts in Japan were borne by the military. They were the biggest item in the budget. By 1930, the Japanese military started to assassinate their financial elite. It took out two finance ministers, two prime ministers, several cabinet-level appointees, and half a dozen senior bankers. You can rack up quite a body count doing this if you piss off the military enough. So the lesson learned on this was simultaneous contractions, when everybody else is doing it, is zero sum against everybody else, and leads to really nasty politics. So Keynes and events overturn austerity. What does it show us? It shows there are fallacies of composition and non-scalability in labor and money markets. What's true about 2 people or 10 people is simply not true about 20 million or five interlinked economies. There are systemic non-linearities and difference that simple cannot be done by type. Investment expectations are not about parsimony. They're about fear. And if everybody's fearful for the future and has myopic, short run expectations, and we look to each other for signals about whether we should be investing next month or not, you discount the time series of the 36 good periods and heavily weight the three in the front. That's why it's hard to get out of a recession. The emetic response, you binge and then you purge, assumes you're at the bottom. People start saving again. You've got [INAUDIBLE] consumption, austerity, you start saving. And the assumption is that saving is automatically investment. But there's a drop there, because you have to invest in a recession. Why would you want to be the guy who takes the chance to invest in a recession? Surely you'd rather be liquid, so everybody tries to sit on a liquidity all at once. But you can't-- in order for you to be liquid, somebody else has to be illiquid. So you end up with a liquidity trap. And that's when you get stuck for 14 years. That's why the Great Depression lasted so long. So because of this, rather than curtail consumption, the austerity response, consumption, to repeat the obvious, is the sole end of economic activity. "General Theory," page 71, if I remember correctly. Lessons learned. It all goes back to redistribution. Democracy is asset insurance for the rich. Don't skimp on the payments. That's what was going in the '20s, and that's what's going on today. Redistribution of debt is reinsurance for democracy, and austerity is anorexia for the economy. That was what was learned by 1940. Oh, how we forget. And why do we forget? We forget because of Germany, because Germany is a very peculiar economy. It is not a liberal economy. It is much closer to Japan than it is to anything else in Europe or the United States. It is, in fact, the original developmental state. What do I mean by that? In 1873, there was a huge stock market bubble in Germany, and it blew up. It was called the Founders Crisis. And liberal economic ideas of the type we've been discussing were completely discredited. At this point in time, there was a guy called Liszt who comes along and says, you know, the funny thing about the Brits telling us all the story about how to get rich, if they had actually done that themselves-- you know what their comparative advantage was in? Wool. They would still be making blankets for the people in Flanders. How come they're running the world? How come they have the biggest navy in the world? How come they make steel when they basically have no iron ore? What the hell is that all about? So he rewrote how you think about international trade. And at the same time that he did this, he, and also the Bismarck who was running the place did what was called the marriage or iron and rye, bringing together the industrialists in the south, the agrarians in the north. You use the surplus from agriculture to basically buy flattened equipment. You bring it in, you reverse engineer it, you do it faster, you do it faster, you build up German industrial capitalism. Big firms, big banks, forced saving, a big role for the state. And it's all driven by exports. There's your difference. But when you're exporting and your sources of demand lie outside your economy, you don't have to worry about internal demand. The Keynesian story makes no sense if you're Germany. Why would you want to stabilize consumption if you're export dependent? Because all you're going to do is raise your wages and prices, and your BMW is going to go from 50,000 to 100,000 real fast, and you're not going to sell them. So if you don't rely on domestic consumption and rely on external consumption, the dynamics of your economy are completely different. What do you care about price control? All this stuff about the neuralgia of the 1920s and the inflation experience, this is a post-war construction. It's really about remaining price competitive in export markets. So you need a strong, independent central bank. What else do you care about? Very important-- competition. You want to have competition over products, so that you have BMW and Audi competing with each other so they can sell more to the Chinese both because they're competing against product quality. You don't get involved in the Apple, Samsung, buy up patents and sue each other in court crap. You do real competition to get real value out at the end of it. Given that the role of the state, these Freiburg liberals-- this is Walter Euken, one of the guys who, post-war, reinvigorates all this stuff. Because after Nazism is discredited, they needed a new thing. And basically it was about the economic constitution, where competition rather than consumption becomes important, and sound money and central bank independence defines the economy. Why is this important? First of all, for 30 years, this is the entire structure of the Euro. If you think about the way the European Union is set up, it's Generalized Ordoliberalism, to give that type of liberalism its name. The commission is the important part, not the parliament. The parliament is a talking shop that very little representative rights or power. Sound money is far more important than output. It's all about the European Central Bank and its policy. It has one target-- fighting inflation, even if there's a deflation going on. Well, what does that reflect? The need for cost competitiveness. What is it that the commission does? The commission basically sets rules. What are those rules about? Competitiveness. What's the largest component of the administrative architecture of Brussels? The Competition Commission. Rules rather than discretion at all times. You can't trust politicians to run the economy-- they'll run inflationary cycles, that will be bad for growth. Yes, if seen through a German perspective. But here's what it misses, a giant fallacy of composition. For you to sell your BMW, somebody else needs to be buying them. For somebody to basically be having an export surplus, somebody needs to have an important deficit. In the aggregate, in theory, it balances out. But if you go way back to that picture I showed of the current account imbalances, there's only one company running a surplus. And the sum of that surplus is the sum of that deficit-- they're almost exactly equivalent. So what you have here is a situation whereby when you generalize the economic principles and institutions of one country across the whole of the EU, which was fine, so long as the banks were spending money all over the place so nobody noticed, it's fine. But once that credit bubble pops, suddenly you all have to be Germany. Tell me, how is Greece and Portugal going to make an Audi? And even of they did, who are they going to sell it to? Who's going to buy it? Imagine the Competition Commission gets its way and everybody becomes more competitive, and they all make exports. Who's going to buy all this crap? The over-tapped American consumer? We're already spending too much already. So you end up with an economy and an economic structure, an economic model for an entire continent which literally cannot work. It makes no sense on a global level, and yet that's the one that it's pursuing. Competitiveness rather than complementarity. And also, you then have idiotic things like debt breaks, Schuldenbremse. This says that nobody can ever have more than a 5% debt on deficit. Really? Because that means everybody has to run a budget surplus. How is that going to happen? That's actually not arithmetically possible, but it doesn't stop them writing rules about it, even if it's arithmetic nonsense. This then leads to Italy. I'm getting there. This guy was the first Prime Minister of Italy and head of the Italian Central Bank post-war. He set up the Bocconi School of Public Finance in Milan. The Bocconi School was famous for two things. Number one, public choice theory. Essentially, states are rent seekers and they can't be trusted. Hey, if I grew up in Italy, I would probably think that about the state, as well, but they generalized it to everybody. They're also very fond of the notion of a European Union as a disciplinary device overriding local democracy and reigning in state spending. The Bocconi School are important because when Cambridge-- qua Cambridge, UK-- blew up in the '70s intellectually and Cambridge and America had their lunch in what was called the Cambridge Capital controversies, the only economics department in Europe that was mathematically sophisticated enough to play with the Americans was the Bocconi School. And they were hard-wired for seeing the state as a bad thing at exactly the time that liberal economics went in the same direction, when it went neoliberal. Consequence of this-- these guys become an aircraft carrier for austerity thinking that goes from Milan to Harvard, which leads us to today, the financial crisis. This is Greenspan's mea culpa. I think there's a flaw in my ideology, and it's this big. And we get to this guy, who's Alberto Alesina, who, just like Joseph Schumpeter, is arguing for emetic economics. And he, too, is the head of the Economics Department of Harvard. He's the guy who came up with what's called the expansionary austerity hypothesis. It's about debt and time and consistency, which is actually that Ricardian equivalence stuff all again. And it basically says the following-- this is the confidence theory thing. This is why you cut spending. So imagine the economy is falling around your ears, you don't know if you're going to have a job tomorrow, your partner is already unemployed, you really don't know about the future, but you really worry about the debt. You just lie awake all night worrying about the debt, as people do. So the government credibly signals that it is going to massively cut government expenditure. And what you do, using your rational expectations that are built into your head-- well, you know the true structural form of the equation governing the economy and the value of the coefficients therein. Big assumption, but put that to one side. You calculate your lifetime budget and your lifetime expenditure in relation to the fact that 20 years from now, because of these state spending cuts now, you'll pay less taxes then. Thereby, you can retro-dict how much extra money you've got now, and everybody goes to Ikea and buys a couch. And that cures the recession. I am not making this shit up. Take away all the math, that's what all these papers say. And what we actually see at the end of it, you got all these countries cases that supposedly show this in the '80s-- Ireland, Sweden, Denmark, et cetera-- and in the book I go through them and show that they do nothing of the kind. What actually happens is, take Canada as the greatest example of this-- the Loonie takes a 40% devaluation from '76 to '86. You're export dependent. You're a commodity exporter. Your major trading partner who takes 75% of your exports is the United States. The United States' economy is nine times the size of your economy. You have a 40% devaluation as the American economy takes off like a rocket between '86 and '92. What do you think is going to happen to Canada's budget surplus? It gets massive. They cut and then it led to growth? No. They grew and then they cut. Because that's what your meant to do. Austerity date is best done in the boom, not the slump. That's what all these states actually do. Cutting in a slump produces a bigger slump. It's really that simple. So this is taken up by the European Central Bank and was called the Ecofin Brief and the G20 finance ministers in 2009. It's published in all its glory in the TCB's 2010 report. All the arguments from David Ricardo, et cetera, and John Stuart and Hume and Smith, I'm not kidding, are in that book. I mean, literally, you could quote them line for line. It's exactly the structure of how they did all the bailouts, and how they did all the stuff in terms of bailing out Greece, et cetera. And there result of this is what I call the greatest bait and switch in history. Because what's actually happened is all that private debt that was generated by the banking system through over-lending is now on the public balance sheet. And to go full circle, all the way back, that means that people like me, who have grown up on the welfare state just now, have to pay for the mistakes of systemically irresponsible bankers. Because you can't tax them themselves because they're too politically powerful. That's why this is fundamentally a problem of politics, and not a problem of economics. Is there a way out of this? People have started to defect. The IMF has started to go. The IMF has calculated now that, what happens when you cut $1 of public spending in the periphery? You lose $1.5 to $1.7 in spending, which is why you get this wonderful negative convexity, where it goes, ah, which is what's happening to periphery economies. You end up with more debt, not less. The rebel alliance-- Romania, Estonia, Bulgaria, Latvia, Lithuania-- they tried to blow up the debt star. They failed. It's been a disaster. Excelgate, that's Reinhart and Rogoff's 90%. There really was nothing there to start with. And we have 25% permanent unemployment in Europe. That is not politically sustainable. So where does it all end? First one, financial repression. You take those banks that are heavily levered and filled with government bonds and you fill them with even more government bonds. Then what you do is lower the payment on it that you get from it, and you lend to maturity. And then what you do is you run a positive inflation. Hence, why central banks are now moving to inflation targets. What does that do? It creates a negative real interest rate. That cures your debt far better than any amount of cutting, which actually doesn't work because it's zero sum against itself. When did we last do this? End of World War II. The liquidation tax accounted for the equivalent of 40% of American GDP being paid back in 10 years, and the American economy boomed at the same time. So there's something very, very important. That's where this one's heading. Who is this bad for? This is totally bad for creditors and really good for debtors. I just took on the largest mortgage in human history because I fully expect this to happen. I'm bar-belled. If the economy recovers, my asset goes up in value. If there's an inflationary cycle, it eats away half my mortgage. Screw them-- I've been paying for their bailouts. Second one. Higher taxes. Carried interest exemption. Mitt Romney pays 15% tax. I pay 30%. You pay 30%. Do you think that's fair? I don't think that's fair. I think that's coming to an end. And we're going to shut down every goddamn tax haven on the planet, as well. Because you know how much is hidden there? $27 trillion in untaxed wealth-- estimate-- is sitting in five tax havens. How many divisions does the Cayman Islands have? None. Let's go get it. It's so much easier than slashing the fire brigade. And the last one, if you think about this as payback for the bailouts who started it all, is Hippocratic economics. First do no harm. The United States was meant to die. We had spent too much. We were the profligate. We were all going to die. Remember all those articles about, oh, it's coming, the great end, the great crash, the whole lot? We've de-levered, we've cleaned up the balance sheets of the financial sector, we're lending again, we've got positive growth. In three years' time-- we actually have stabilized the debt already. In three years, we'll be effectively reducing it. The Brits are in for a decade of recession. Ireland has a lost generation because they bailed their banks and they did austerity. Periphery Europe is stuck with 25% permanent unemployment. This doesn't work. It is a human disaster. But most of all, it's politics. Because it's always about one thing. Somebody got all the benefits, then they cost all the costs, now they want somebody to pay for the costs while they keep all the benefits. That's what this is really all about. Thank you. [APPLAUSE] MARK BLYTH: Went on a bit longer than anticipated, despite talking faster than JFK on speed. Sorry about that. AUDIENCE: Much as I'd like to take out a huge mortgage and buy stuff, there's something of a bubble going on around here. Any other suggestions for how to take advantage of this? MARK BLYTH: Well, as I switch onto my financial adviser mode. How do you make money in a positive inflationary environment? It's not easy, but it's not impossible. If you have a look at companies that did really, really well in the 1980s, late '70s, early '80s, they tended to be sort of conglomerate trusts. So they owned a little bit of everything. That's like the Abu Dhabi Investment Corporation, whose unofficial slogan is, we own half a percent of everything that isn't nailed down on the entire planet. And the idea behind it is that you don't know where the upside is coming from. So what you should be is maximally diversify. It's like an index fund. So basically, anything at all that is internally diversified, so buying cut shares in companies that have that type of structure is probably the best way of bar-belling yourself against them. But ultimately, you know, investing in debt markets is probably a bad idea right at this point. But it's still sort of-- at the end of the day, about this paranoia that inflations lead to hyperinflations, it's total crap. When I went through the book and did the research on this, I wanted to-- I'm married to-- background information-- I'm married into a bunch of Germans. Well, I'm only married to one, but the whole family comes with them, right? And my [GERMAN], as I like to call him, my father-in-law, [GERMAN], he's a classic German. He's like 71 years old, he's retired, and he still saves. What the? You'll die-- what are you doing? Why? He's totally hardwired for saving, and he's totally paranoid about inflation. So I went and read a lot about the German hyperinflation. And it was deliberate government policy to stuff the French over reparations. I mean, they did it quite deliberately. And the weird about it was after they did it, it ended in eight months. And the entire economy was stabilized within 12. And then it grew for five years. And then what actually happened was austerity, through the economy of a cliff, and that's when the Nazis came to power. So we have this story about the least degree of inflation leads to some kind of infinity curve hyper-convexity where, boom, off it goes. And it's simply not true. Post-war Europe ran positive rates of inflation with positive real rates of growth all the way through the postwar period until about 1980. So the inflation panic is there. AUDIENCE: So I've heard Krugman and others bring up Japan as an example to support these kind of arguments. Can you just talk a bit about how they're able to run a high debt for so long and things don't seem to-- MARK BLYTH: Sure, sure. Absolutely. I actually think these guys are wrong about Japan. I think what goes on in Japan is actually deeply structural. There is a wonderful book by guy called Sven Steinmo, called "The Evolution of the Modern State." And he has a chapter on Japan. And if you ever wanted to read, I think, the definitive story on Japan, this is it. He spent two years there on an Abe fellowship and had access to all the people. Well, it was two books. It was Richard Koo's "Holy Grail of Macroeconomics." So basically what happens is Japan goes through a balance sheet recession. What's a balance sheet recession? Basically, your companies are de-levering but don't want to tell anyone because if they do, there will be a run on them. And everybody's complicit together because they've all over borrowed. So basically, you have this kind of slow bleeding that goes on as it's sort of monetized by the central bank, and it ends up in debt. So you're not growing. And that's sort of the obvious part of the story. The less obvious part of the story goes like this. Go back to 1986. There's a thing called the Plaza Accord. The Plaza Accord was when the United States turns around to its two major trading partners, Japan and then West Germany, and said, our exchange rate is too high. People are buying dollars, we're doing well just now. And it's killing our exports. You guys are wiping us out. Remember the whole paranoia about Japan that went on? They were going to take over the world, all that. You ever see the film, "Rising Sun," Michael Crichton? Possibly the most racist film ever made in human history, but put that to one side. So Japan's going to take everything over, blah, blah, blah, the rest of it. And then, of course, what actually happens is they do the exchange rate thing, the United States exchange rate goes down, the German one and the Japanese one goes up. Now, the Japanese economy is entirely export dependent. It's sort of like Germany on steroids. So what they do is they move the plant and equipment from the Japanese home islands out to the second tier tigers. So you start to get investment in Vietnam, Malaysia, all these places, and they move the entire thing with the supplier networks, the whole lot. Well, the way that the Japanese welfare state was constructed, it was all in-house to the firm. It was meant to be cradle to grave, but the firm took care of you. Well, the firm has just broken the social contract. So how did people protect themselves? They wanted another asset they could have that would have a positive upside, that would retain its value, and they could sell it in their retirement. What did they buy en masse? Real estate. So you get a giant real estate bubble. The real estate bubble gets so out of control that it popped and the banking system can't support it. That collapses and that starts the recession. But the important part is the sociological story. You've got a cultural and generational shift. Because you've got a very old population who are now 45 years old, facing unemployment, with a very, very narrow safety net for the first time. So what do they do when the government gives them money to spend to stimulate the economy? They stick it under the mattress. It doesn't go anywhere. It gets hoarded. So the savings rate goes up. And where do they put the savings? In the post office account and in the bank account. And what do the bank and the post office do with it? They buy government bonds. So that's why you end up with this massive extension in debt. Now, the thing is, the Japanese propensity to consume is really, really low, particularly the higher up the demographic you get. So 80-year-olds are not just buying bonds and then liquidating them in retirement, they're actually keeping them whole and handing them onto the next generation. So you've got an inter-generational debt transfer going on. So the story that basically it's just a monetary policy story in, you know, Japan, I think that's wrong. I think there's actually a deeply structural problem that's going on there, and it goes all the way back to the Plaza Accord. So that's my short version of Sven Steinmo's argument, but I find it quite convincing. AUDIENCE: How can an individual state in the EU, like Ireland or something, try to fix things for itself with all the constraints under it? MARK BLYTH: They can't. Look, and it's good. Because you're in the Euro. So once you're in the Euro, it's a kind of a one-time game. Because the problem was if you're Argentina and you tie yourself to the dollar, as they did back in the day, back in the late 1990s into 2000, and then you have the default. And they had a default because Argentina is the graveyard of all bad economic policies gone wrong, there's no doubt about that. But also because their major trading partner is Brazil. And basically, the Real had a 40% exchange rate gain, and basically it screwed up all their exports and the whole thing fell down. Now, because they were just on a peg, they actually still had their own domestic currency. So they could go, to hell with the peg. We've still got it. And then you lock up the banks and people bang on the doors and all that sort of stuff. But you still have your currency. Ireland doesn't have a pound anymore. I mean, literally, the bits of paper don't exist. So if you were going to get out of the Euro-- just think about the complexity of this for a second-- you would have to kind of freeze time. Everybody freezes, some kind of government agency with a time machine would freeze time, you'd go around, you'd vacuum up all the bills out of everybody's wallets, the whole lot, and you'd stamp them all and reissue them the new currency, and then you'd unfreeze time. And then you would have an economic crisis. So just that alone adds a level of complexity to it which makes it just incredibly difficult. Bigger countries like France and Italy can do this. The Italian economy, North Italy, is actually globally competitive, totally solvent, the whole lot. The south is a basket case. It's a bit like the north and south of the United States. Shh. Anyway. But you get transfers across the region, that's what keeps it going. The problem is Greece has nothing to export. It really doesn't. It has olive oil. But so does Italy, and they can make more of it. Spain makes even more of that. Do you know when you buy your EVOO and it says, Italian olive oil? It's actually Spanish olives they've bought and they brought to Italy and then they grind them and call it Italian olive oil. So that's all zero sum against itself. So if you don't have something to export, then the devaluation thing that you'll get won't benefit you because you don't have anything. And all you'll do is end up with hyperinflation because your imports become so incredibly expensive. So Ireland, Greece, Portugal, they are stuck because they've got nothing to sell. That's it. So they're kind of trapped in this worst of all possible worlds. Ireland is really screwed for a whole generation. The debt to GDP figures you see in Ireland are a big, fat lie. Because they basically book services exports from this company as exports. So basically, the profits from this farm go to an office in Dublin. Has anybody ever been to the office in Dublin? No? There's about 25 people who work there. And your entire corporate profits get declared through them, because you only pay 12.5% tax. So that 12.5% gets booked as an Irish services export and appears in their balance of payments. Well, it's complete paper. It's nothing. It's complete garbage. And they also have all the bad assets from their banks that blew up and this thing called NAMA, which is a super bad bank, and that's never coming back. And that's off balance sheet. So when you add it all together, Ireland is actually worse than Greece. Shh. Just don't tell the Irish. AUDIENCE: Speaking of people, what do you think about Iceland, how they dealt with their financial? MARK BLYTH: Iceland is a brilliant example of no good deed goes unpunished. So when I started all this off, I was a member of this thing called the Warwick Commission on Financial Form. And you know, the crisis happens, and people are like, it's the shadow banks. And I'm like, what's a shadow bank? I mean, you need to do a little bit of catch-up on this. So at first, I bought the whole narrative of too big to fail. Systemic interconnections, the rest, the whole lot, blah, blah, blah, blah. And by the time I finished the book, I said, no, I actually totally don't buy this-- I think we should have let them fail. Oh, but what about systemic risk, all the rest of it? Well, I know what lost GDP is, I know how much unemployments cost, I know all that. I know the real costs of not bailing them. And more to the point, the banking system, even though it's de-levered, is actually more concentrated now than it was in 2007. So Citibank is even too bigger to fail. And the European system is that on steroids. So you've basically given someone not just a banking license with a subsidy, an extortion racket on the taxpayer. And that's just, it is literally criminal. Best example of this-- UBS. Fined $1.2 billion a few months back for doing terrorism financing and money laundering with drug dealers. Now, if you or I did this, we would be in the jail. They get a fine. Why do they get a fine? Because if you are an investor in an American or American-licensed broker/dealer entity-- a big bank-- and one of your corporate officers is charged with a criminal liability, you are under legal obligation to withdraw your investments. So if UBS is actually criminally charged, or their senior officers are charged. And then CalPERS has to pull the money out. If CalPERS pulls the money out along with everybody else, what happens to that bank? So what happens to the system? So you're basically playing systemic moral hazard as a business model. This is screwed up beyond belief. So Iceland, to finish this one, basically let their banks fail. Now, a lot of the debt, most of the debt was externally held, so the cost of that went on to others. But here's the interesting part of the story. All of the super geniuses who were working in the banks engineering derivatives now had to get a real job. So what happened was the domestic economy, the real economy, rebounded, because all these start-ups happened. Because all these really bright people went, shit, I need something else to do. So they started doing all these new businesses which didn't appear before. They became a huge hub for online gaming, because you can stick the servers in the ground-- and it's bloody cold-- and you've got all the people with the math skills who can do the software engineering and make the whole thing work. So there were all of these positive externalities of actually letting them fail. Their unemployment level is now about one point higher than Germany . Compare it with Iceland, which is 14% on the official rate, and that's with migration going out. So the people who did this, the government that came in and basically allowed this to happen, it's been a bit tough. They actually do things like pay back the debt and are fiscally responsible. So they've just been voted out, and the people who blew up the banks in the first place are now back in power. No good deed goes unpunished. AUDIENCE: I don't know if you're familiar with what happened in Australia. I'm from Australia. But people have largely missed the financial crisis. And there are two stories running. And I don't know if you know which one is the-- anyway, they're competing. One is saying that, well, the government did spending and gave people money. And they spent it. And that saved the economy. And the other story running is that, no, it's the mining boom. We just dig everything up, sell it to China, China went well. And it has nothing to do with what the government did. Have you got a view on that? MARK BLYTH: The second one is completely right. And the way you can see this is you can't trade the Chinese currency easily, because of capital controls, et cetera. But what you can do is basically look at the shadow markets on the Chinese currency versus the Australian dollar. And they move like this. And it is because, basically, Australia literally is owned by China. I mean, people say this about the United States. Oh, China owns the USA. And it's like, well look, only 17% of bills are actually owned by China. And it's brilliant. Because for the past 30 years, we've been giving them bits of paper that bear 2% net. And they've been giving us televisions. It's a sweet deal. I don't know why anybody would ever want to end it. It's brilliant for us. The Australian one is the other way around. They actually do own your assets completely. Because if it wasn't for the western Australian mining boom, and just all the commodities they're sucking out at the peak of a commodity cycle, I mean, do you really think a house in Perth would cost 2 million Australian dollars? And it does. It's totally that. It's totally the mining boom. So what that means is either the commodity cycle peaks or China slows down, Australia is in serious trouble. Now, the price to income multiples in Sydney are 13 to 1. So you need to marry two people and have family money in order to get a house. So it's not 3 times your income, it's 13 times your income for a three bedroom flat in a nice part of Sydney. That's a colossal housing bubble, and it's Chinese liquidity that's pumping it. If that every goes away, boom. AUDIENCE: The housing bubble has never crashed in Australia, unlike everywhere else. MARK BLYTH: Yeah, absolutely. And you know what? All bubbles pop. It is just a question of time. AUDIENCE: I was hoping you could talk a little bit about the BRIC countries, and especially what Brazil needs to be doing. MARK BLYTH: Brazil needs to do what Brazil's been doing, which is awesome. So quite primer on the Brazilian political economy. For years and years and years they had one of the highest Gini coefficients in the world. They were incredibly unequal. And they had a problem because wealth being so concentrated meant that the people who make effective investment decisions decided that their own economy was too risky, because it would either be run by the military or run by the communists or run out of town. So they would take their money and they would put it in Citibank, which is nice and secure. And you got a lesser rate of return, but you don't mind because you own everything, anyway. So that's the way it went on for years and years, until it got to a point where basically you had to spend so much money on private kidnap insurance and mining your house against the people who would try and kill you, that they did a deal with a guy called Lula. Lula u to run the Worker's Party. So the guy who ran the Worker's Party, the lefty guy, comes in and basically does exactly as I said on the bottom of that slide. Democracy is asset insurance for the rich-- stop skimping on the payments. So did this strategy whereby they got BNDES, the Brazilian National Development Bank, to bank-- their lending portfolio, by the way, is twice the size of the World Bank-- to subsidize domestic corporations so that they could multinational. So you've got companies like Embraer, the aircraft company, the big cement company, and the others, that are now globally successful corporations. Because of that expansion, bankrolled by the development bank, what they do is they tax the companies on their earnings abroad, bring that back in, and they set up something called Bolsa Familia, which is the welfare state that Brazil never had. This has squeezed the income distribution like this at the same time as it has gone up, which enables the Brazilians to finally build a middle class. It empowers the middle class. And it dis-empowers the durational land-owning elites. So what you end up with-- there's a little fixey-do with domestically high interest rates to keep these guys happy. Well, what you've actually done is to engineer is to engineer a kind of new developmental welfare state, which has actually been great for Brazilian growth and has actually brought down the Gini coefficient. Because of this, everybody wants to buy Brazilian assets, which is why the Real is going up. And they're export-dependent, so they're freaking out. So what they've done is they've put inward capital controls on inward investment. And usually, the big fear is you put your money in, they put up capital controls, you can't get it out, it's expropriation. They're doing it totally different. They're like, you want to come here? Dead easy. Pay a transactions tax and a deposit. Because if you're not coming in for the long term, forget about sitting here earning high interest rates just because you can. So they're making it difficult for that money to come in. But as a growth node in a big country, it is happening nonetheless. So the Real is going up, the economy is slowing down. But what they've done over the past 10 years, I think, is nothing short of remarkable. BORIS DEBIC: Thank you, Mark. [APPLAUSE]

Seniority

Seniority of members are determined by the Yang di-Pertuan Agong.[1] But based on common practice, members are ranked by the number of consecutive terms as either Senator or Member of the House and seniority date (i.e. date of first swearing in as either Senator of Member of the House). Senators and Members of the House who swear in on the same day are later ordered numerically according to the Hansard.

Vacancies

Senate

House of Representatives

Current seniority list

Note that the italicised name of constituency represents that of the Senate.

Name M. C. Current Party Seniority Date CTN Previous terms Remarks
Tan Kok Wai House P123 Cheras PH–DAP 6 October 1986 9 7th–15th Former MP for Sungai Besi
Special Envoy of the Prime Minister to China (2018-2020)
Richard Riot Jaem House P199 Serian GPSSUPP 3 December 1990 8 8th–15th Special Envoy of the Prime Minister to East Asia (2020-2022)

Minister (2013-2018)

Mahiaddin Md Yasin House P143 Pagoh PN-BERSATU 7 June 1995 9 5th–6th, 9th–15th Prime Minister (2020-2021)
Deputy Prime Minister (2009-2015)
Minister (1995-2015, 2018-2020)
Deputy Minister (1982-1986)
Parliamentary Secretary (1981-1982)
Hishammuddin Hussein House P153 Sembrong BN–UMNO 7 June 1995 7 9th–15th Former MP for Tenggara
Minister (1999-2018, 2020-2022)
Mohd. Shafie Apdal House P189 Semporna WARISAN 7 June 1995 Minister (2004-2015)
Ahmad Zahid Hamidi House P075 Bagan Datuk BN–UMNO 7 June 1995 Deputy Prime Minister (2015-2018, 2022-present)
Leader of the Opposition (2018-2019)
Alexander Nanta Linggi House P215 Kapit GPS–PBB 20 December 1999 6 10th–15th Minister (since 2020)
Deputy Minister (2013-2018)
Henry Sum Agong House P222 Lawas GPS–PBB 20 December 1999 Deputy Minister (2015-2018, 2020-2022)

Former MP for Bukit Mas

Tiong King Sing House P217 Bintulu GPS–PDP 20 December 1999 Minister (since 2022)

Special Envoy of the Prime Minister to China (2020-2022)

Bung Moktar Radin House P187 Kinabatangan BN–UMNO 20 December 1999
Ronald Kiandee House P183 Beluran PN-BERSATU 20 December 1999 Minister (since 2020)
Deputy Speaker of the House (2008-2018),
Chairman of PAC (2018-2019)
Teresa Kok Suh Sim House P122 Seputeh PH–DAP 20 December 1999 Minister (2018-2020)
Fong Kui Lun House P120 Bukit Bintang PH–DAP 20 December 1999 7 8th, 10th–15th
Kula Segaran Murugeson House P065 Ipoh Barat PH–DAP 14 July 1997 6 9th, 11th–15th Former MP for Telok Intan

Minister (2018-2020)

Azalina Othman Said House P157 Pengerang BN–UMNO 17 May 2004 5 11th–15th Deputy Speaker of the House (2020-2021)
Minister (2004-2009, 2015-2018, since 2022)
Fadillah Yusof House P194 Petra Jaya GPS–PBB 17 May 2004 Deputy Prime Minister (2022-present)

Senior Minister (2020-2022)
Minister (2013-2018, since 2020)

Aaron Ago Dagang House P210 Kanowit GPS–PRS 17 May 2004 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)

Minister (since 2022)

Ismail Abdul Muttalib House P086 Maran PN-PAS 17 May 2004 Deputy Minister (2013-2018, since 2020)
Ismail Sabri Yaakob House P090 Bera BN–UMNO 17 May 2004 Prime Minister (2021-2022)
Deputy Prime Minister (2021)
Senior Minister (2020-2021)

Minister (2008-2018, 2020-2022)
Leader of the Opposition (2019-2020)

Wee Ka Siong House P148 Ayer Hitam BN–MCA 17 May 2004 Minister (2004-2018, since 2020)
Chong Chieng Jen House P196 Stampin PH–DAP 17 May 2004 Deputy Minister (2018-2020)
Lim Guan Eng House P043 Bagan PH–DAP 6 October 1986 7 7th–9th, 12th-15th Minister (2018-2020)

Former MP for Kota Melaka

Abdul Hadi Awang House P037 Marang PN-PAS 3 December 1990 7 8th–10th, 12th-15th Special Envoy of the Prime Minister to Middle East (2020-2022)

Leader of the Opposition (2002-2004)

Saravanan Murugan House P072 Tapah BN–MIC 28 April 2008 4 12th-15th Minister (since 2020)
Deputy Minister (2008-2018)
Noraini Ahmad House P147 Parit Sulong BN–UMNO 28 April 2008 Minister (since 2020)
Deputy Minister (2008-2009)
Chairman of PAC (2019-2020)
Hamzah Zainudin House P056 Larut PN-BERSATU 28 April 2008 Minister (2015-2018, since 2020)

Deputy Minister (2008-2015)

Nancy Shukri House P193 Santubong GPS–PBB 28 April 2008 Former MP for Batang Sadong

Minister (2013-2018, since 2020)

Hasbi Habibollah House P221 Limbang GPS–PBB 28 April 2008 Deputy Minister (since 2020)
Ahmad Maslan House P164 Pontian BN–UMNO 28 April 2008 Deputy Minister (2009-2018, since 2022)
Shamsul Anuar Nasarah House P055 Lenggong BN–UMNO 28 April 2008 Minister (2020-2021) Deputy Minister (since 2022)
William Leong Jee Keen House P097 Selayang PH–PKR 28 April 2008
Gobind Singh Deo House P106 Damansara PH–DAP 28 April 2008 Former MP for Puchong

Minister (2018-2020, since 2023)

Teo Nie Ching House P163 Kulai PH–DAP 28 April 2008 Former MP for Serdang
Deputy Minister (2018-2020, since 2022)
Ngeh Koo Ham House P068 Beruas PH–DAP 28 April 2008
Nga Kor Ming House P076 Teluk Intan PH–DAP 28 April 2008 Former MP for Taiping

Deputy Speaker of the House (2018-2020)
Minister (since 2022)

Anthony Loke Siew Fook House P128 Seremban PH–DAP 28 April 2008 Minister (2018-2020, since 2022)

Former MP for Rasah

Lim Lip Eng House P114 Kepong PH–DAP 28 April 2008 Former MP for Segambut
Siti Zailah Mohd. Yusoff House P023 Rantau Panjang PN-PAS 28 April 2008 Deputy Minister (since 2020)
Wilfred Madius Tangau House P170 Tuaran PH-UPKO 20 December 1999 6 10th-12th, 13th-15th Minister (2013-2018)
Wan Azizah Wan Ismail House P124 Bandar Tun Razak PH–PKR 20 December 1999 Deputy Prime Minister (2018-2020)
Leader of the Opposition (2008, 2015-2018)

Former MP for Permatang Pauh & Pandan

Shahidan Kassim House P003 Arau PN-PAS 6 October 1986 5 7th-8th, 13th-15th Minister (2013-2018, 2021-2022)
Mas Ermieyati Samsudin House P134 Masjid Tanah PN-BERSATU 24 June 2013 3 13th-15th Deputy Minister (2015-2018, 2020-2022)
Wilson Ugak Kumbong House P216 Hulu Rajang GPS–PRS 24 June 2013 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Rubiah Wang House P197 Kota Samarahan GPS–PBB 24 June 2013 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Abdul Rahman Mohamad House P079 Lipis BN–UMNO 24 June 2013 Deputy Minister (since 2020)
Anyi Ngau House P220 Baram GPS–PDP 24 June 2013
Ikmal Hisham Abdul Aziz House P027 Tanah Merah PN-BERSATU 24 June 2013 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Takiyuddin Hassan House P021 Kota Bharu PN-PAS 24 June 2013 Minister (2020-2022)
Sivakumar Varatharaju Naidu House P066 Batu Gajah PH–DAP 24 June 2013 Minister (2022-2023)
Sim Tze Tzin House P052 Bayan Baru PH–PKR 24 June 2013 Deputy Minister (2018-2020)
Wan Hassan Mohd Ramli House P039 Dungun PN-PAS 24 June 2013
Alice Lau Kiong Yieng House P211 Lanang PH–DAP 24 June 2013 Deputy Speaker of the House (since 2022)
Steven Sim Chee Keong House P045 Bukit Mertajam PH–DAP 24 June 2013 Minister (since 2023)
Deputy Minister (2018-2020, 2022-2023)
Oscar Ling Chai Yew House P212 Sibu PH–DAP 24 June 2013
Ahmad Marzuk Shaary House P020 Pengkalan Chepa PN-PAS 24 June 2013 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Former MP for Bachok
Wong Chen House P104 Subang PH–PKR 24 June 2013 Former MP for Kelana Jaya
Ramkarpal Singh House P051 Bukit Gelugor PH–DAP 9 June 2014 Deputy Minister (2022-2023)
Anwar Ibrahim House P063 Tambun PH–PKR 29 March 1982 8 7th-10th, 12th-13th, 14th-15th Prime Minister (2022-present)

Deputy Prime Minister (1993-1998)
Leader of the Opposition
(2008-2015, 2020-2022) Former MP for Permatang Pauh & Port Dickson

Mohamad Sabu House P111 Kota Raja PH–AMANAH 3 December 1990 5 8th–10th, 14th-15th Minister (2018-2020, since 2022)

Former MP for Nilam Puri, Kubang Kerian & Pendang

Chow Kon Yeow House P046 Batu Kawan PH–DAP 20 December 1999 5 10th–12th, 14th-15th Former MP for Tanjong
Saifuddin Abdullah House P082 Indera Mahkota PN-BERSATU 28 April 2008 3 12th, 14th-15th Minister (2018-2022)
Deputy Minister (2008-2013)

Former MP for Temerloh

Dzulkefly Ahmad House P096 Kuala Selangor PH–AMANAH 28 April 2008 Minister (2018-2020)
Wee Jeck Seng House P165 Tanjung Piai BN-MCA 28 April 2008 Deputy Minister (2008-2010, 2020-2022)
Syed Saddiq Syed Abdul Rahman House P146 Muar MUDA 16 July 2018 2 14th-15th Minister (2018-2020)
Yeo Bee Yin House P103 Puchong PH–DAP 16 July 2018 Minister (2018-2020)

Former MP for Bakri

Muhammad Bakhtiar Wan Chik House P053 Balik Pulau PH–PKR 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2018-2020)
Hannah Yeoh Tseow Suan House P117 Segambut PH–DAP 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2018-2020)

Minister (since 2022)

Isnaraissah Munirah Majilis House P169 Kota Belud WARISAN 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2018-2020)
Wong Kah Woh House P060 Taiping PH–DAP 16 July 2018 Chairman of PAC (2020-2022)
Deputy Minister (since 2023)

Former MP for Ipoh Timor

Kesavan Subramaniam House P062 Sungai Siput PH–PKR 16 July 2018
Chang Lih Kang House P077 Tanjong Malim PH–PKR 16 July 2018 Minister (since 2022)
Ali Biju House P205 Saratok PN-BERSATU 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Kelvin Yii Lee Wuen House P195 Bandar Kuching PH–DAP 16 July 2018
Akmal Nasrullah Mohd Nasir House P160 Johor Bahru PH–PKR 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Wong Shu Qi House P152 Kluang PH–DAP 16 July 2018
Cha Kee Chin House P130 Rasah PH–DAP 16 July 2018
Sanisvara Nethaji Rayer Rajaji House P050 Jelutong PH–DAP 16 July 2018
Hassan Abdul Karim House P159 Pasir Gudang PH–PKR 16 July 2018
Jonathan Yasin House P179 Ranau GRS 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Willie Mongin House P198 Puncak Borneo GPS-PBB 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Ahmad Fahmi Mohamed Fadzil House P121 Lembah Pantai PH–PKR 16 July 2018 Minister (since 2022)
Pang Hok Liong House P142 Labis PH–DAP 16 July 2018
Chan Foong Hin House P172 Kota Kinabalu PH–DAP 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Larry Sng Wei Shien House P209 Julau PBM 16 July 2018
Prabakaran Parameswaran House P115 Batu PH–PKR 16 July 2018
Nik Nazmi Nik Ahmad House P118 Setiawangsa PH–PKR 16 July 2018 Minister (since 2022)
Syed Ibrahim Syed Noh House P144 Ledang PH–PKR 16 July 2018
Muslimin Yahaya House P092 Sungai Besar PN–BERSATU 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Khoo Poay Tiong House P138 Kota Melaka PH–DAP 16 July 2018
Mordi Bimol House P192 Mas Gading PH–DAP 16 July 2018
Jalaluddin Alias House P126 Jelebu BN–UMNO 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2021-2022)
Rosol Wahid House P038 Hulu Terengganu PN-BERSATU 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Tuan Ibrahim Tuan Man House P024 Kubang Kerian PN-PAS 16 July 2018 Minister (2020-2022)
Nik Muhammad Zawawi Salleh House P028 Pasir Puteh PN-PAS 16 July 2018
Ahmad Fadhli Shaari House P022 Pasir Mas PN-PAS 16 July 2018
Abdul Latiff Abdul Rahman House P031 Kuala Krai PN-PAS 16 July 2018
Hanifah Hajar Taib House P215 Mukah GPS–PBB 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (since 2020)
Sabri Azit House P012 Jerai PN-PAS 16 July 2018
Ahmad Tarmizi Sulaiman House P013 Sik PN-PAS 16 July 2018
Shaharizukirnain Abdul Kadir House P034 Setiu PN-PAS 16 July 2018
Ahmad Amzad Hashim House P036 Kuala Terengganu PN-PAS 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Jeffrey Gapari Kitingan House P180 Keningau GRS–STAR 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020)
Mohd. Shahar Abdullah House P084 Paya Besar BN–UMNO 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Ahmad Johnie Zawawi House P207 Igan GPS–PBB 16 July 2018
Yusuf Abd. Wahab House P206 Tanjong Manis GPS–PBB 16 July 2018
Lukanisman Awang Sauni House P218 Sibuti GPS–PBB 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Arthur Joseph Kurup House P182 Pensiangan BN–PBRS 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (since 2020)
Awang Hashim House P011 Pendang PN-PAS 16 July 2018 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Syed Abu Hussin Hafiz Syed Abdul Fasal House P059 Bukit Gantang PN-BERSATU 16 July 2018
Husain Awang Senate Terengganu PAS 17 July 2018 2
Ti Lian Ker Senate At-large BN–MCA 10 August 2018 2 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Md. Nasir Hashim Senate At-large PH–BERSATU 27 August 2018 2
Razali Idris Senate At-large PN–BERSATU 27 August 2018 2
Ramli Mohd Nor House P078 Cameron Highlands BN-UMNO 11 March 2019 2 14th-15th Deputy Speaker of the House (since 2022)
Kesavadas Achyuthan Nair Senate Negeri Sembilan PH-DAP 20 March 2019 2
Ahmad Azam Hamzah Senate Negeri Sembilan PH-PKR 9 May 2019 2
Vivian Wong Shir Yee House P186 Sandakan PH–DAP 1 July 2019 2 14th-15th
Mohamad Alamin House P176 Kimanis BN-UMNO 26 January 2020 Deputy Minister (2022-present)
Tengku Zafrul Aziz Senate At-large BN-UMNO 9 March 2020 2 Minister (2020-present)
Rita Samariah Senate At-large GPS-PRS 22 June 2020 2
Susan Chemarai Anding Senate At-large GPS-PBB 22 June 2020 2
Vell Paari Samy Vellu Senate At-large BN-MIC 2 September 2020 2
Mohd Hisamudin Yahaya Senate Putrajaya BN-UMNO 4 October 2021 1
Bobbey Ah Fang Suan Senate Sabah GRS–GAGASAN 5 January 2021 2
Teo Eng Tee Senate At-large PN-GERAKAN 19 July 2021 2
Wan Martina Wan Yusoff Senate Kelantan PN-PAS 24 August 2021 1
Ajlis Sitin Senate Pahang BN-UMNO 25 August 2021 1
Juhanis Abdul Aziz Senate Pahang BN-UMNO 25 August 2021 1
Aziz Ariffin Senate Perlis BN-UMNO 26 August 2021 1
Seruandi Saad Senate Perlis BN-UMNO 26 August 2021 1
Arman Azha Abu Hanifah Senate At-large BN-UMNO 26 October 2021 1
Dominic Lau Hoe Chai Senate At-large PN-GERAKAN 23 November 2021 1
Nelson Renganathan Senate At-large BN-MIC 23 November 2021 1
Noraini Idris Senate Sabah BN-UMNO 10 December 2021 1
Shamsuddin Abdul Ghafar Senate Perak BN-UMNO 20 December 2021 1
Zurainah Musa Senate At-large BN-UMNO 22 December 2021 1
Azhar Ahmad Senate At-large IND 21 March 2022 1
Mohd Fatmi Che Salleh Senate At-large BN-UMNO 25 April 2022 1
Lim Pay Hen Senate Johor BN-MCA 26 June 2022 2
Ahmad Ibrahim Senate Sarawak GPS-PBB 22 July 2022 1
Mohamed Haniffa Abdullah Senate At-large BN-MIC 20 September 2022 1
Ros Suyati Alang Senate At-large BN-UMNO 20 September 2022 1
Saifuddin Nasution Ismail Senate At-large PH-PKR 3 December 2022 1 Minister (2018-2020, since 2022)
Former MP for Machang & Kulim-Bandar Baharu
Zambry Abdul Kadir Senate At-large BN-UMNO 3 December 2022 1 Minister (since 2022)
Mohd Naim Mokhtar Senate At-large IND 3 December 2022 1 Minister (since 2022)
Fuziah Salleh Senate At-large PH-PKR 9 December 2022 1 Deputy Minister (2018-2022, since 2022)
Former MP for Kuantan
Saraswathy Kandasami Senate At-large PH-PKR 9 December 2022 1 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Mohamed Khaled Nordin House P156 Kota Tinggi BN-UMNO 3 December 1990 6 8th-12th, 15th Minister (2004-2013, since 2022)

Deputy Minister (1999-2004)

Suhaili Abdul Rahman House P166 Labuan PN-BERSATU 20 December 1999 3 10th-11th, 15th
Hasni Mohammad House P151 Simpang Renggam BN-UMNO 17 May 2004 2 11th, 15th Former MP for Pontian
Liew Chin Tong House P162 Iskandar Puteri PH-DAP 28 April 2008 3 12th-13th, 15th Deputy Minister (2018-2020, since 2022)

Former MP for Bukit Bendera & Kluang

Mohd Rafizi Ramli House P100 Pandan PH-PKR 24 June 2013 2 13th, 15th Minister (since 2022)
Che Mohamad Zulkifly Jusoh House P033 Besut PN-PAS 24 June 2013 Former MP for Setiu
Idris Ahmad House P058 Bagan Serai PN-PAS 24 June 2013 Minister (2021-2022)

Former MP for Bukit Gantang

Johari Abdul Ghani House P119 Titiwangsa BN-UMNO 24 June 2013 Minister (2016-2018, since 2023)

Deputy Minister (2015-2016)

Mumtaz Md. Nawi House P019 Tumpat PN-PAS 19 December 2022 1 15th
Doris Sophia Brodi House P202 Sri Aman GPS-PRS 19 December 2022 Deputy Speaker of Dewan Negara (2012-2016)
Mohd Suhaimi Abdullah House P004 Langkawi PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Mohd Radzi Md Jidin House P125 Putrajaya PN–BERSATU 19 December 2022 Senior Minister (since 2020)
Minister (2020-2022)
Deputy Minister (2018-2020)
Lim Hui Ying House P049 Tanjong PH–DAP 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Aiman Athirah Sabu House P113 Sepang PH–AMANAH 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Wan Ahmad Fayhsal Wan Ahmad Kamal House P029 Machang PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (2020-2022)
Fadhlina Sidek House P047 Nibong Tebal PH-PKR 19 December 2022 Minister (since 2022)
Ahmad Yahaya House P008 Pokok Sena PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Khairil Nizam Khirudin House P081 Jerantut PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Iskandar Dzulkarnain Abdul Khalid House P067 Kuala Kangsar PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Armizan Mohd Ali House P175 Papar GRS 19 December 2022 Minister (since 2022)
Mohamad Hasan House P131 Rembau BN-UMNO 19 December 2022 Minister (since 2022)
Ewon Benedick House P174 Penampang PH-UPKO 19 December 2022 Minister (since 2022)
Zaliha Mustafa House P141 Sekijang PH-PKR 19 December 2022 Minister (since 2022)
Adly Zahari House P135 Alor Gajah PH-AMANAH 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Khairul Firdaus Akbar Khan House P185 Batu Sapi GRS 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Adam Adli Abd Halim House P137 Hang Tuah Jaya PH-PKR 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Mohammad Yusof Apdal House P188 Lahad Datu WARISAN 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Mustapha Sakmud House P171 Sepanggar PH-PKR 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Huang Tiong Sii House P208 Sarikei GPS-SUPP 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (since 2022)
Siti Aminah Aching House P177 Beaufort BN-UMNO 19 December 2022 Deputy Minister (2022-2023)
Zahir Hassan House P116 Wangsa Maju PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Yuneswaran Ramaraj House P140 Segamat PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Matbali Musah House P178 Sipitang GRS 19 December 2022
Suhaimi Nasir House P184 Libaran BN-UMNO 19 December 2022
Shahelmey Yahya House P173 Putatan BN-UMNO 19 December 2022
Sh Mohmed Puzi Sh Ali House P085 Pekan BN-UMNO 19 December 2022
Aminolhuda Hassan House P149 Sri Gading PH-AMANAH 19 December 2022
Manndzri Nasib House P155 Tenggara BN-UMNO 19 December 2022
Tan Kar Hing House P071 Gopeng PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Chow Yu Hui House P080 Raub PH-DAP 19 December 2022
Tan Hong Pin House P145 Bakri PH-DAP 19 December 2022
Andi Muhammad Suryandy Bandy House P191 Kalabakan BN-UMNO 19 December 2022
Ramanan Ramakrishnan House P107 Sungai Buloh PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Lee Chean Chung House P105 Petaling Jaya PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Ganabatirau Veraman House P110 Klang PH-DAP 19 December 2022
Syahredzan Johan House P102 Bangi PH-DAP 19 December 2022
Rodziah Ismail House P099 Ampang PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Mohd Sany Hamzan House P101 Hulu Langat PH-AMANAH 19 December 2022
Azli Yusof House P108 Shah Alam PH-AMANAH 19 December 2022
Jimmy Puah Wee Tse House P158 Tebrau PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Onn Abu Bakar House P150 Batu Pahat PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Mohd Isam Mohd Isa House P133 Tampin BN-UMNO 19 December 2022
Adnan Abu Hassan House P129 Kuala Pilah BN-UMNO 19 December 2022
Shamshulkahar Mohd. Deli House P127 Jempol BN-UMNO 19 December 2022
Edwin Banta House P214 Selangau GPS-PRS 19 December 2022
Richard Rapu House P204 Betong GPS-PBB 19 December 2022
Young Syefura Othman House P089 Bentong PH-DAP 19 December 2022
Syerleena Abdul Rashid House P048 Bukit Bendera PH-DAP 19 December 2022
Lo Su Fui House P190 Tawau GRS-PBS 19 December 2022
Roy Angau Gingkoi House P203 Lubok Antu GPS-PRS 19 December 2022
Mohd Shafizan Kepli House P201 Batang Lupar GPS-PBB 19 December 2022
Chong Zhemin House P070 Kampar PH-DAP 19 December 2022
Howard Lee Chuan How House P064 Ipoh Timor PH-DAP 19 December 2022
Mohammed Taufiq Johari House P015 Sungai Petani PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Riduan Rubin House P181 Tenom KDM 19 December 2022
Verdon Bahanda House P167 Kudat IND 19 December 2022
Rodiyah Sapiee House P200 Batang Sadong GPS-PBB 19 December 2022
Amirudin Shari House P098 Gombak PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Aminuddin Harun House P132 Port Dickson PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Chiew Choon Man House P219 Miri PH-PKR 19 December 2022
Wetrom Bahanda House P168 Kota Marudu KDM 19 December 2022
Mohd Syahir Che Sulaiman House P025 Bachok PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Afnan Hamimi Taib Azamudden House P009 Alor Setar PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Ku Abdul Rahman Ku Ismail House P006 Kubang Pasu PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Zahari Kechik House P030 Jeli PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Azman Nasrudin House P017 Padang Serai PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Mohd Hasnizan Harun House P094 Hulu Selangor PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Muhammad Islahuddin Abas House P154 Mersing PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Hassan Saad House P016 Baling PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Wan Saiful Wan Jan House P042 Tasek Gelugor PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Khlir Mohd Nor House P026 Ketereh PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Mohd Misbahul Munir Masduki House P057 Parit Buntar PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Ahmad Yunus Hairi House P112 Kuala Langat PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Zulkifli Ismail House P139 Jasin PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Alias Razak House P035 Kuala Nerus PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Ahmad Fakhruddin Fakhrurazi House P010 Kuala Kedah PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Zulkafperi Hanapi House P095 Tanjong Karang PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Nurul Amin Hamid House P007 Padang Terap PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Roslan Hashim House P018 Kulim-Bandar Baharu PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Halimah Ali House P109 Kapar PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Kamal Ashaari House P087 Kuala Krau PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Bakri Jamaluddin House P136 Tangga Batu PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Mohd Nazri Abu Hassan House P014 Merbok PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Muhammad Fawwaz Mohamad Jan House P044 Permatang Pauh PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Siti Mastura Mohamad House P041 Kepala Batas PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Azahari Hasan House P061 Padang Rengas PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Abdul Ghani Ahmad House P005 Jerlun PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Abdul Khalib Abdullah House P091 Rompin PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Zakri Hassan House P002 Kangar PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Rushdan Rusmi House P001 Padang Besar PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Mohd Azizi Abu Naim House P032 Gua Musang PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Salamiah Mohd Nor House P088 Temerloh PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Nordin Ahmad Ismail House P074 Lumut PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Muhammad Ismi Mat Taib House P069 Parit PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Kalam Salan House P092 Sabak Bernam PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Wan Razali Wan Nor House P083 Kuantan PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Jamaluddin Yahya House P073 Pasir Salak PN-PAS 19 December 2022
Fathul Huzir Ayob House P054 Gerik PN-BERSATU 19 December 2022
Lingeshwaran R. Arunasalam Senate Penang PH-DAP 7 March 2023 1
Amir Md Ghazali Senate Penang PH-PKR 7 March 2023 1
Hussin Ismail Senate Terengganu PN-PAS 15 March 2023 1
Abun Sui Anyit Senate At-large PH-PKR 20 March 2023 1
Anifah Aman Senate Labuan PCS 20 March 2023 1 Minister (2008-2018)

Former MP for Kimanis & Beaufort

Awang Sariyan Senate At-large Independent 20 March 2023 1
Isaiah Jacob Senate Kuala Lumpur PH (PKR) 20 March 2023 1
Low Kian Chuan Senate At-large Independent 20 March 2023 1
Manolan Mohamad Senate Aboriginese PH (PKR) 20 March 2023 2
Mohd Hasbie Muda Senate At-large PH (AMANAH) 20 March 2023 1
Mohd Hatta Ramli Senate At-large PH (AMANAH) 20 March 2023 1 Deputy Minister (2018-2020)

Former MP for Kuala Krai & Lumut

Noorita Sual Senate At-large PH (DAP) 20 March 2023 1 Former MP for Tenom
Roderick Wong Siew Lead Senate At-large PH (DAP) 20 March 2023 1
Abd Nasir Idris Senate Kedah PN (PAS) 20 March 2023 1
Musoddak Ahmad Senate Kedah PN (PAS) 20 March 2023 1
Sivarraajh Chandran Senate At-large BN (MIC) 20 March 2023 1 Former MP for Cameron Highlands
Mujahid Yusof Rawa Senate At-large PH (AMANAH) 25 May 2023 1 Minister (2018-2020)
Former MP for Parit Buntar
Nur Jazlan Mohamed Senate At-large BN (UMNO) 15 June 2023 1 Deputy Minister (2015-2018)
Former MP for Pulai
Mustafa Musa Senate Malacca BN (UMNO) 1 August 2023 1
Suhaizan Kayat House P161 Pulai PH (AMANAH) 9 September 2023 1
Nik Mohamed Abduh Nik Abdul Aziz Senate Kelantan PN (PAS) 19 September 2023 1 Former MP for Pasir Mas and Bachok
Ahmad Samsuri Mokhtar House P040 Kemaman PN (PAS) 2 December 2023 1
Abdul Halim Suleiman Senate Johor BN (UMNO) 4 December 2023 1
Michael Mujah Lihan Senate Sarawak GPS (PBB) 11 December 2023 1
Amir Hamzah Azizan Senate At-large Independent 12 December 2023 1 Minister (since 2023)
Zulkifli Hasan Senate At-large Independent 12 December 2023 1 Deputy Minister (since 2023)
Anna Bell Suziena Perian Senate At-large GRS (GAGASAN) 5 March 2024 1
Pele Peter Tinggom Senate At-large GPS (PDP) 5 March 2024 1

See also

Footnotes

References

  1. ^ "Susunan Keutamaan Persekutuan" (PDF). Bahagian Istiadat dan Urusetia Persidangan Antarabangsa, Jabatan Perdana Menteri (in Malay). 13 November 2014. Retrieved 13 September 2018.
This page was last edited on 10 May 2024, at 06:17
Basis of this page is in Wikipedia. Text is available under the CC BY-SA 3.0 Unported License. Non-text media are available under their specified licenses. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc. WIKI 2 is an independent company and has no affiliation with Wikimedia Foundation.